Copyright
By
Mulong Wang
2001
The Dissertation Committee for Mulong Wang Certifies that this is the
approved version of the following dissertation:
Financial Derivatives in Corporate Risk Management
Committee:
Patrick L. Brockett
Supervisor’s name, Supervisor
Richard D. MacMinn
Co-Supervisor’s name, Co-Supervisor
Jonathan F. Bard
Member’s name
Douglas J. Morrice
Member’s name
Thomas W. Sager
Member’s name
Financial Derivatives in Corporate Risk Management
by
153 trang |
Chia sẻ: huyen82 | Lượt xem: 2505 | Lượt tải: 1
Tóm tắt tài liệu Financial Derivatives in Corporate Risk Management, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
Mulong Wang, B.S.
Dissertation
Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of
the University of Texas at Austin
in Partial Fulfillment
of the Requirements
for the Degree of
Doctor of Philosophy
The University of Texas at Austin
August 2001
UMI Number: 3036610
________________________________________________________
UMI Microform 3036610
Copyright 2002 by ProQuest Information and Learning Company.
All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against
unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.
____________________________________________________________
ProQuest Information and Learning Company
300 North Zeeb Road
PO Box 1346
Ann Arbor, MI 48106-1346
Dedicated to Helen,
My wife
Acknowledgements
I want to thank all those kind people who advised or helped my
dissertation research.
I am greatly indebted to my supervisors, Drs. Patrick Brockett
and Richard MacMinn. This dissertation would not have been finished
without their kind guidance, discussion, and encouragements. It has
been an extremely valuable experience to study and work under their
supervision.
I also would like to thank my dear wife, Helen. With her
consistent encouragements and help, I can dedicate to this research.
Drs. Jonathan Bard, Douglas Morrice and Thomas Sager
provided numerous comments on this dissertation. Their service on
my dissertation committee is greatly appreciated.
Colleagues in Center of Risk Management and Insurance and
Center of Management and Operations for Logistics also provided a lot
of help in my PhD student career. Their discussions inspired a lot of
this dissertation research and other research projects.
v
Financial Derivatives in Corporate Risk Management
Publication No.
Mulong Wang, Ph.D.
The University of Texas at Austin, 2001
Supervisors: Patrick L. Brockett and Richard D. MacMinn
This dissertation addresses how the weather derivative hedges
the corporate risk, how to price the indexed derivative as an exotic
derivative instrument, and the implications of basis risk embedded in
the weather derivative.
The traditional one-dimension financial market framework is
expanded to include the weather index. Under this expanded
framework, the stock market values of the unhedged and hedged
firms are studied first. This provides the base to investigate the
pricing formula for weather derivative under the expanded framework.
It is found that both financial and actuarial approaches are integrated
vi
to price the weather derivative.
A positive risk management paradigm must provide the criteria
to choose the optimal hedging instrument(s) for separable risks. This
dissertation provides the criteria to choose optimal hedging contract
set to hedge the weather risk, under different corporate leverage
levels. It has been found that weather derivative outperforms the
traditional commodity forward in most of the scenarios. When
corporate leverage levels increase, the positive role of the weather
derivative or the commodity forward diminishes.
Basis risk arises by introducing the standard weather index,
and providing the industry-standard payment when the weather
derivative is exercised. The implication of basis risk is investigated
under the same expanded framework. It is found that in most of the
scenarios, basis risk is innocuous.
vii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Chapter I. Introduction…………………………………………………1
1.1 Background……………………………………………….2
1.2 Literature on Risk and Risk Management………….7
1.3 The Frontier of Risk Management ………………….11
1.4 Weather Risk and Weather Derivatives ……………13
Chapter II. Weather Derivative and Its Valuation……………….17
2.1 Introduction…………………………………………………17
2.2 Basic Model …………………………………………………28
2.3 Valuation of Weather Derivative………………………..38
Chapter III. Weather Derivative and Commodity Forward……..48
3.1 Scenario sets…………………………………………………49
3.2 Optimal Hedging……...…………………………………….58
Chapter IV. Basis Risk and Its Implications……………………….86
4.1 Introduction………………………………………………….86
4.2 Implications of Basis Risk…………………………………89
viii
Appendix I. Figures ………………………………………………………106
Appendix II. Extensions of Principle of Increasing Uncertainty…125
Reference…………………………………………………………………….135
Vita……………………………………………………………………………142
ix
Chapter I
Introduction
This dissertation addresses how the weather derivative hedges
the corporate risk, how to price the indexed derivative as an exotic
derivative instrument, and the implications of basis risk. These topics
are summarized in an expanded uncertainty model. Under this
framework, different hedging instruments for studying the optimal
hedging portfolios are compared.
In economics and finance literature, risk has been a subject of
interest and study in many fields including management science,
decision science, and psychology. With the new risks being
continuously discovered, innovative strategies and tools were created
to manage them or transfer them. In this chapter, the background of
risk creation, identification and the importance of risk management
are discussed first. In the second chapter, the economic and financial
literature on risk and risk management, most of which concentrates
on the mechanism of financial derivatives to hedge the risk, or
insurance contract to transfer the individual risk or corporate risk, is
reviewed. The third chapter studies the new frontier of risk
management strategies and tools. In the last part, the weather
1
derivative is introduced as an example of novel risk management tool.
The focus of this dissertation is to study how the weather derivative
hedges the specific risk and its positive effects on creating value for
the hedged firms. The valuation of the indexed derivative was
investigated and the comparison of different hedging instruments in
the corporate finance framework was made, to investigate the optimal
hedging strategies under the presence of separable risks.
This dissertation investigated the pricing problem of the
weather derivative. In addition, the comparison of the weather
derivative and the commodity forward under different corporate
leverage scenarios was made. Finally, the implications of basis risk
were discussed.
1.1 Background
In general, risk is the uncertainty in the future, and has been
traditionally separated into two categories: pure risk or speculative
risk. A pure risk is a chance of loss or no loss, and a speculative risk
is characterized as a chance of loss or gain. An example of pure risk is
catastrophe risk, such as an earthquake, flood or hurricane.
Gambling is an example of speculative risk, which may yield a gain or
2
loss in the end.
In the economics and finance literature, the definitions of pure
risk and speculative risk differentiate insurance from finance. Much of
the insurance literature has concentrated on the management of pure
risk and much of the finance literature on risk management has
concentrated on the management of speculative risk. However, recent
applications of risk management have blurred the line between these
fields. For example, the Catastrophe (CAT) Bond, created to hedge the
catastrophic event risk, is an example of securitization, seen mostly in
the mortgage market. However, the separation between insurance and
finance paradigms was blurred by the creation of the CAT bond. Like
investing in traditional bonds, i.e., Treasury bonds or corporate
bonds, investors bear the speculative risk. The cedent, paying the
premium to the safe trust, obtains the protection as traditional
insurance provides. Therefore, CAT bond is not only an investment
vehicle for the investors, but also a hedging vehicle for the cedents,
which represents a vehicle combining both pure risk and speculative
risk. With the discovery of new risks, new hedging instruments will be
developed to further blur the line of pure risk and speculative risk,
making the distinction between insurance and finance even more
3
ambiguous.
Nowadays, the risk-management process is becoming an
increasingly important financial area for virtually all corporations.
With the dramatically growing costs of losses from different risk
sources, business firms can gain a competitive cost advantage
through the development of a set of cost-effective and efficient risk-
management strategies. The advantages of a well-managed risk
management program include not only a lower total loss cost and an
improved business bottom line, but also an increased predictability of
future losses and cost, which ensures greater budget control and
reduced ambiguity for future net revenue stream. A less risky
corporate operation and payoff preserve more value for the risk-averse
investors and therefore are preferred. In addition, a good risk
management program will immunize the corporation from the sharp
loss in the lower tail of the loss distribution curve [c.f. Stulz (1996)].
Another advantage for an efficient risk management program may be
a lower cost of employment, since workers are more willing to be
employed in a financially stable firm with a lower wage than work in a
risky firm. In summary, an efficient risk management program will
not only reduce the level of losses incurred by a firm, but it will also
4
help the firm improve its financial performance and employee morale.
From a corporate finance perspective, risk management is
becoming a more important field. For instance, during 1990, U.S.
domestic firms spent more than $6001 billion on projects related to
risk management, such as product liability, workers’ compensation,
employee health, dental, disability and pension benefits, and other
insurance- related products. Research has disclosed that firms
typically pay approximately 40% of their payroll costs on risk
management activities with health care and employee benefits alone,
which account to approximately 26% of the cash flow of a typical firm.
For instance, General Motors Corp. spent more than $4 billion on
health care costs for its employees and is now attempting to cut the
costs by transferring some of it to employees. Recently, large jury
verdicts awarding compensations to customers or employees of
business have skyrocketed, making risk management even more
important for businesses. These types of costs of uncontrolled risk
can, and have, bankrupted corporations while clearly focusing other
corporations on the importance of managing and controlling their own
5
1 See George Rejad’s Principle of Risk Management and Insurance.
risks.
An integral part of managing risk is to transfer the financial
impacts of such risks to another party, if possible, or if the transfer is
not too expensive. Historically, a common mechanism for such
transfers is to use the insurance industry to retain these transferred
risks, by assuming the insurance companies are risk neutral.
Theoretically, the law of large numbers, which states that as the
number of independent and identically distributed risks becomes
arbitrarily large, the standard deviation of the average loss
distribution converges toward zero, makes the insurance industry
viable and profitable. In fact, apart from government regulation,
insurance may still be the single most important mechanism for
regulating risk and safety in society, though many alternative risk-
transferring vehicles have been introduced and implemented recently.
Risk management and insurance costs and protection are also
important for individual consumers. Individuals traditionally
purchase automobile, homeowners, and other insurance to stabilize
their financial conditions, and prepare for uncontrollable risks such
as accidents, death or illness.
6
1.2 Literature on Risk and Risk Management
In the economics and finance literature, risk and risk
management have drawn considerable attention. One of the major
instruments to manage risk is insurance. At the corporate level, the
role and impact of using insurance to transfer risk have been studied
extensively [c.f. MacMinn (1987a); Mayers and Smith (1987); MacMinn
(1989); Garven and MacMinn (1993), MacMinn (1999)]. Insurance is
an efficient instrument to manage the pure risk [c.f. MacMinn (1999)],
and preserves corporate value when there is a probability of
insolvency. At the individual level, the demand for insurance in an
investor’s optimal portfolio was also investigated [c.f. Doherty (1981);
Doherty (1984); Doherty and Schlesinger (1983a); Doherty and
Schlesinger (1983b); Mayers and Smith (1982); Mayers and Smith
(1983)]. In general, insurance has been demonstrated to be an
indispensable risk-management instrument. It was found that
insurance should be included in the optimal investment portfolio
when pure risk is present.
The role that insurance plays in financial markets can be
explained by distinguishing between risks. The finance paradigm
7
characterizes risk as systematic or non-systematic, or equivalently,
diversifiable or non-diversifiable. The insurance paradigm, however,
classifies risks as either pure or speculative. The different definition of
risk separated finance from insurance literatures. For a long time,
finance and insurance were separated because of this line, and the
convergence of hedging by financial instruments and insurance
contracts was largely ignored.
The main purpose of risk management is to preserve or create
values by selecting optimal contract sets. For firms, corporate value is
preserved by the inclusion of hedging instruments in the financial
contracts. For individual investors, more expected utility is created by
the inclusion of insurance and/or other hedging contracts in the
investment portfolio. Before the demise of the Glass-Steagall Act in
the 1990s, insurance and finance industries were treated separately.
Recent mergers, particularly the merger between Citicorp and
Travelers, represent the convergence of finance and insurance in
practice. These new acts and mergers changed the conditions and
more risk management instruments are combined with insurance and
financial techniques.
It is not hard to follow the convergence trend. The main
8
function of financial markets is to efficiently allocate the risk and
facilitate the redistribution of risk. The development of financial
markets has been benefited from the better understanding of
separable risks. When the risk becomes more transparent, it
facilitates the redistribution process in the financial market.
Insurance contract is a subset of financial contracts. If the
combination of insurance and financial hedging contracts creates
more value for the firm, it is preferred. The recent convergence in the
finance and insurance industries enhances the main function of risk
management, that is, by efficiently combining risk management
techniques, more value is created. The development of catastrophe
bond is a good example of the convergence of financial and insurance
techniques. By tapping the pure catastrophic risk into the financial
market, a better allocation of risk and resource is achieved between
firms and investors. Consequently, more value is generated.
Therefore, there is a need to extend the current economics and
finance paradigms to better understand how the financial
instruments can hedge the risk and allow an efficient allocation of
risk bearing and resources. Based on the extended paradigms, further
studies on how to combine the different hedging instruments to reach
9
the optimal allocation of risks and resources can then be made.
A robust model to incorporate and compare different hedging
instruments has not yet been developed in the literature. A better
understanding of risks and risk comparisons is needed, though a
perspective for comparing risks has been provided [c.f., Rothschild
and Stiglitz (1970)]. The process of risk being generated and valued
must also be well understood to compare different hedging
instruments. The optimal hedging contract set can then be chosen to
preserve the most value.
The recent developments of risk management instruments and
financial markets reveal the continued separation of risks so that
each can be redistributed at the least cost to society. To understand
this behavior, more fundamental notions and understanding of risks
are required. A robust model is needed to allow the risks to be valued
separately and so the choices for an optimal hedging contract set can
be made.
10
1.3 The Frontier of Risk Management
With the convergence of finance and insurance, many new risk
management tools were developed. Alternative Risk Transfer (ART) is
one subset of them. With the rapid identification and separation of
new risks, many of the ART solutions are tailored to specific client
problems and offer integrated risk management solutions, for
instance, a multi-year or multi-trigger cover. ART solutions focus on
increasing the efficiency of the risk transfer, broadening the coverage
of insurable risks and tapping the capital markets for additional
capacity. These risk management solutions make it easier for a
company to efficiently manage those risks from which it gains no
comparative advantage in managing itself. The development of ART is
consistent with the objective of an efficient risk- management solution
by allowing institutional clients to allocate more capital to their core
businesses, thereby generating higher returns.
Over the last few years, ART solutions have expanded rapidly.
The initial focus is on captives. Such solutions will allow companies to
deal with high-frequency risks in a more cost-efficient way than
through traditional industrial insurance. Since 1980s, captives have
been increasingly used as a financing instrument for some low-
11
frequent, but high-severity risks which could not be placed in the
traditional ways. Despite the continuous erosion of tax benefits and
the persistently low premium rates in the traditional market during
the 1990s, captives are set to come into their own as holistic risk
management tools.
The potential for the sustained growth of new risk management
strategies and tools is considerable. Captive is one example. Other
new instruments have been created and implemented. Attempts to
transfer insurable risks directly to capital market investors have
received special attention over the past a few years. This can be
through the securitization of risks in the form of insurance bonds or
via derivative transactions. In this way, the policyholder obtains
additional capacity without incurring any credit risk, in particular, for
the catastrophe losses, while investors are able to further diversify
their investment portfolios with the invention of new instruments
such as CAT bonds.
The rapid development of risk management instruments must
be based on a widely acceptable economic and/or financial
mechanism for the instruments to efficiently hedge the risks. For
instance, weather derivatives may be a good example to hedge the
12
weather-related risks. To tap the capacity of financial markets, a
widely understandable pricing formula and the positive role of adding
weather derivative into the optimal contract set of the firm must be
investigated. In addition, the advantages and disadvantages of using
those new hedging instruments must also be understood for them to
be widely implemented and traded.
1.4 Weather Risk and Weather Derivatives
As different as they may be, the business and production
processes of utility companies, theme parks, fashion houses, ice-
cream manufacturers, building companies and sports goods
manufacturers, all have one thing in common: their business success
is highly dependent on prevailing weather conditions. Nearly everyone
talks about the weather but few do anything about it. Virtually all
sectors of the economy are directly or indirectly subject to the
influence of the weather in some form or other. For instance, daily
beer consumption can be increased if the temperature rises. Weather
risks are important to the energy and power supply industry because
their product price is highly sensitive to the spot weather conditions.
The agriculture industry is another example. Production level is highly
13
correlated with weather conditions, which affects profit.
Unusual weather patterns have increasingly prompted
companies whose results are affected by the prevailing weather
conditions to seek protections against effects of this kind. An
unusually warm winter may cut the revenue figure of a natural gas
company, but an unusually cold winter may sharply increase the
demand of natural gas.
Hedging weather risks not only will yield a more predictable
revenue stream, but also increase the shareholder’s value. The energy
and power sectors may benefit most from the new tools to hedge
weather-related risks, with other hedging instruments including
weather derivatives in the firm’s portfolio will stabilize the net revenue
stream and reduce the loss of revenue in the lower tail of the weather-
risk distribution.
A weather derivative is an exotic derivative because the
underlying asset is not negotiable or traded. It is based on the
weather index, such as Cool Degree Days or Heating Degree Days,
which influence the volume of the goods, particularly the energy
products, traded in the market. Therefore, the major effect of weather
derivatives is to hedge the volume risk, instead of the price risk. For
14
instance, a warmer-than-average winter season may drive the natural
gas demand lower, thus a weather put2 option will be in the money
and will provide compensations to the option buyer, since the weather
index (HDD in this case) is below the strike value.
The notion behind a weather hedge is that the results of
weather-sensitive sectors can be subject to great volatility, even if
prices remain unchanged, due to a change in demand or volume.
An important, but unresolved issue is a unanimous pricing
formula for the weather derivative. This prevents the weather
derivative from being traded efficiently in the market. The underlying
asset is not traded and the traditional Black-Sholes model cannot be
applied. In addition, the assumption of the log-normal distribution of
the weather index, such as CDD or HDD, is difficult to verify due to
the lack of a robust empirical test and consideration of seasonal
change. To solve this issue, the dynamism of the weather (trends) and
the actuarial weather forecast information must be included in the
pricing model to best reflect the value of weather derivatives.
In general, risk is a commodity that may be produced,
exchanged or preserved. The way in which businesses and society
15
2 A put option will be in the money when the index is below the strike value. In the
assess, control and transfer risk has been examined extensively and
with the invention of new risk management tools being studied
continuously. This dissertation is an attempt to examine how weather
derivatives are incorporated into the corporate contract sets, how to
price the indexed derivatives, and the implications of the basis risk.
The Appendix is an expansion of the uncertainty model [c.f., MacMinn
and Holtmann (1983)], including more stochastic inputs, to examine
whether the widely cited Principle of Increasing Uncertainty (PIU) may
still hold in this extended model. Chapter two discusses the inclusion
of the weather derivative into the firm’s hedging contract set and
valuation of the weather derivative. Chapter three delineates several
scenarios based on corporate-leverage levels. For each scenario, the
impacts of different hedging strategies on the corporate value are
studied. In chapter four, implications for the corporate payoff and
corporate value are studied when the basis risk is present.
16
warmer winter, the HDD index will be lower, since less heating is needed.
Chapter II
Weather Derivatives and Its Valuation
2.1 Introduction
2.1.1 Weather Risk and The Creation of Weather Derivatives
In recent years, several unique conditions, e.g., unpredictable
weather conditions that affect corporate revenue, combined with the
need to manage risks produced one of the novel financial products of
the last decade: weather derivative. The historical circumstances that
accelerated the development of the trading market include: unusual
weather conditions in different regions, and change of the demand for
weather-associated commodities, causing possible price risks. These
extreme weather patterns exposed the high level of weather-related
risk embedded in the operations of many companies that, as a result,
affected both their revenues and net earnings. For example, an
unusually cool summer will decrease the demand for ice cream or
electricity consumption because of the lesser use of air conditioning,
and an unusually cold winter will increase the demand for natural gas
17
for heating purpose as in the past winter of 2000. In fact, virtually
every sector of the economy is affected by the weather to one extent or
another.
Energy products may be the most sensitive to unusual weather
conditions. Weather remains the single largest variable in the energy
spot-market price. According to research by Koch Industrial and
Utility Services [c.f., Richter (1998)], a 10 percent colder-than-normal
temperature in summer can decrease the natural gas spot price by 15
percent. If average heating-season temperatures rise 1.43 degrees
Fahrenheit above normal, the drop in demand for natural gas will
outweigh the increase in demand that occurs naturally each year to
satisfy economic growth, forcing prices down overall. Meanwhile,
electric utilities also exhibit heightened weather sensitivity in the
summer, and hydroelectric utilities are affected not only by
temperature anomalies, but also by snow and rain anomalies. Recent
data for the unit price of natural gas over the past few years3 clearly
shows a strong negative correlation between the temperature and the
18
3 These data were kindly provided by Enron Capital.
spot price for natural gas in Henry Hub4 (see Figure A in Appendix II).
To measure the correlation between weather conditions and
earnings, it is necessary to have a generally acceptable way to
interpret the weather conditions in different seasons, particularly the
summer and winter. In general, weather conditions are interpreted by
the introduction of a weather index in different seasons. A widely
accepted weather index is Cooling-Degree-Days (CDD) in the summer
or Heating-Degree-Days (HDD) in the winter. The daily HDD may be
defined as the maximum of zero and the difference between 65
degrees Fahrenheit and the daily average temperature, where the
daily average temperature is the average of the maximum and
minimum temperatures (midrange) recorded at a designated reporting
station during a 24-hour period beginning at midnight. That is, if we
let the daily average temperature be iT , the daily number of “heating
degrees” is i iHDD max(65 T ,0)= − and the accumulated “heating-
19
4 Henry Hub is one of the major marketplace that Enron Capital uses to trace the
energy commodity price in different seasons. It provides research data to illustrate
degree-days” (HDD) over one month (30 days) period ending at date t
is
30
t t i 1
i 1
X HDD
− +
=
= ∑ 5. Hence, the larger the HDD, the colder the winter,
and more heating may be needed. Similarly, in the summer season,
the daily number of “cooling degrees” is i iCDD max(T 65,0)= − and the
accumulated “cooling-degree-days” (CDD) over a 30-day period ending
at date t is
30
t t i 1
i 1
X CDD
− +
=
= ∑ . It follows that a cool summer may have
an overall low CDD numerical value.
With broad applicability ranging from electric utilities to long-
underwear companies to theme parks, the weather-derivative market
has the potential to exceed the $200-billion electricity market,
according to Enron Capital & Trade Inc. The growing weather
derivative market may help control its effects on businesses. Through
October 2000, there are more than a dozen companies actively
engaged in the transactions of weather derivatives, making market
capitalization about $2 billion6. The weather derivative is designed to
manage the weather risk, a risk that does not have an immediate and
20
the relationship between energy commodity price and temperature.
5 Therefore, the accumulated HDD by day 5 will be the sum of
5 4 1HDD ,HDD ,...,HDD .
6 Provided by Swiss Reinsurance Co.
direct impact on other risks. It is usually written on an index of the
weather conditions, such as CDDs or HDDs, and can take the form of
calls, puts, swaps, caps, collars, or floors. The weather-derivative
market is in many ways a perfect area for the development of risk-
management products. The need for protection is universal and the
information about weather conditions is widely available. By efficiently
targeting volumetric risk in situations in which price-based
derivatives have previously fallen short, weather derivatives provide
the ability to combine hedges on weather-related risks, such as
temperature or precipitation, with a more typical price-based hedge
on energy commodities, such as natural gas or electricity tied to a
weather index.
A simple._. interpretation of weather options is provided in the
following table:
21
Table 1
Option
Type
Hedge For Exercised While Option Value
HDD
Call
Unusually Cold
Winter
HDD>Strike Value f(HDD-Strike Value)*
HDD
Put
Unusually
Warm Winter
HDD<Strike Value f(Strike Value-HDD)*
CDD
Call
Unusually Hot
Summer
CDD>Strike Value f(CDD-Strike Value)*
CDD
Put
Unusually Cool
Summer
CDD<Strike Value f(Strike Value-CDD)*
(*The option value will be dependent on the difference of actual weather
index and strike values, i.e., it is a function of this difference.)
A more complicated hedging structure may be constructed by a
combination of the above option types, and varies according to
customer needs. One of the earliest examples of a weather-derivative
deal can be dated back to July 1996, when the power marketing
group of Aquila Energy structured a weather hedge for Consolidated
Edison Co.’s Megawatt Hour Store in New York City. The transaction
was based on the Cooling-Degree-Days (CDD) for the month of August
1996 in New York City’s Central Park. In this contract, the embedded
risk was that in a cooler-than-normal month spot-market prices for
power would be lower than the fixed price at which Consolidated
Edison Co. had purchased the commodity. In addition, a cooler
summer will cut the electric sales for its Megawatt Store, causing
revenue shortfalls. By giving it a rebate for a cooler-than-normal
22
summer, Consolidated Edison Co. had the opportunity to recoup the
lost opportunities in the spot market. The detailed option structure
was: if accumulated CDDs in August 1996 were from 0 to 10% below
the expected 320 as weather stations did, the company received no
discount to the power price, but if the accumulated CDDs were 11 to
20% below normal (320 in this case), Consolidated Edison Co.
received a $16,000 discount in total. From 20 to 30% below normal,
the discount value will be increased to $32,000, and if the total CDDs
are more than 30% below 320, the maximum discount in total was
$48,000. In fact, August did have some muggy and cooler days, which
reduced the total CDDs and provided protections for Consolidated
Edison Co., which was what it wanted.
One of the major obstacles to the universal acceptance of
weather derivatives is that its valuation stays unresolved. This is
because the underlying “asset” (weather index as HDD or CDD) is
untradeable. This untradeable index separates the weather derivative
from other traditional hedging instrument, because there is no basis
to price it as a financial derivative. The underlying “asset” of the
weather derivative is based on data such as temperature, which
influences the trading volume of other goods. Usually the weather
23
index, i.e., the underlying “asset” in the weather derivative, can be
interpreted as CDD, i.e., cooling-degree-days, or HDD, heating-degree-
days. This challenging valuation problem must be resolved to tap the
weather derivative to the greater financial market. Two competing
paradigms exist: one is based on the application of actuarial
techniques, and the other is based on the Black-Sholes approach to
the pricing of derivatives. The unique valuation challenges of weather
derivatives may lead to the emergence of a hybrid approach and a new
theory of valuation.
A weather hedge is important because it can stabilize the
forecast for the future revenue, or income stream, for the weather-
sensitive sectors, thus a well-predictable business can result in
increased shareholder value7. The objective of risk management is to
preserve or create values for the firm. If the revenue of the firm is
sensitive to the weather conditions, for instance, an energy firm,
hedging with weather derivatives will recoup part or all the revenue
loss due to negative weather conditions. When there is a risky
leverage, the insolvency probability may be reduced or eliminated by
24
7 As illustrated by the following sections, a hedged firm generally will have less risky
production than unhedged one. By taking a less risky position, corporate value is
increased.
hedging with weather derivatives. Therefore, the bond value is
preserved, and more corporate value is achieved. For individual
investors, investing in the energy firms hedged with weather derivative
reduces the overall risk in the portfolio. Assume that the investors are
risk-averse, a portfolio with the same expected return but less risk
will be preferred, since more expected utility is achieved, i.e., more
value is created for the investors.
The development of weather derivatives also represents one of
the recent trends toward the convergence of insurance and finance
[c.f., MacMinn (2000)]. By efficiently tapping capital markets, this
convergence will transfer the risk to a much larger capital capacity
pool. The creation of weather derivatives also challenges another
fundamental difference in the way that insurance and financial
industries solve the problem of risk management. In general, the
property/casualty insurance industry uses the principle of
diversification, pooling many uncorrelated risks and charging a
premium based on actuarial probabilities of occurrence of different
risks and their correlations. Financial derivatives in risk management
are based on the option pricing and hedging algorithms, which were
originally developed in the 1970s. Which paradigm(s) should be
25
selected to price the weather derivatives still remains unclear. This
paper is an attempt to price it in an expanded economic model, by
integrating both the actuarial and financial approaches.
2.1.2 Literatures on Economics and Finance
One of the fundamental research topics on the weather
derivative is how to price this new hedging instrument. Although the
structure of the weather derivative and the mechanism of how it
hedges the weather risk have been extensively studied [c.f., Leggio and
Lien (2000), Muller and Grandi (2000), Richter (1998)], little research
has been done to provide an explicit explanation of how to price the
weather derivative. In addition, most of the literature does not present
a model where the weather-related risk was incorporated into a robust
economic framework, as an explicit source of uncertainty. Economic
and finance literature on the theory of the firm has concentrated on
the uncertainty arising either from the demand of its product or from
the firm’s technology [c.f., Leland (1972), MacMinn and Holtmann
(1983)]. In these studies, firms had a single source of risk: a one-
dimension uncertainty framework. None of the models had included
26
multiple sources of risk. In fact, one unique characteristic of weather
risk is its independence with most other risks. Consequently, it may
be considered as a second source of risk, in addition to other existing
risk in the corporate finance literature.
Another implication of using the weather derivative is from the
basis risk. Though basis risk has been extensively interpreted recently
[c.f., MacMinn (2000)], few studies quantified basis risk according to
the corporate finance perspective. It is widely known that the basis
risk arises from using a standard industry index. By using the
standard index, some of the problems often hampering risk
management, such as moral hazard and adverse selection, are
eliminated. Basis risk may also arise when a standard index is used.
Some of the most recent empirical work on corporate hedging
behavior [c.f., Haushalter (2000)] revealed that firms would prefer to
use hedging instruments with little basis risk. An explicit explanation
in a theoretical framework has not yet been provided and the
implications of basis risk for corporate hedging remains unclear.
An economic model to explicitly incorporate weather risk into
the firm’s payoff structure was presented in this chapter. Several
important questions arising from using the weather derivatives were
27
addressed. For example, how to quantify the weather risk in an
incomplete financial market; whether the incorporation of weather
derivatives in the firm’s contract set adds value; whether the role of
weather derivatives can be duplicated by other hedging instruments
such as swaps or forwards, and if so, an alternative pricing formula
may be provided for the weather derivative based on the no arbitrage
principle; what is the optimal contract set to hedge the weather; what
are the positive and negative impacts by using different set of hedging
instruments? Chapter four discusses further whether the basis risk
should be hedged or retained under different conditions.
2.2 Basic Model
In the standard finance literature, there exists an economic
state set = ωeZ [0, ] , where the economic state ∈e ez Z spans the space
ω+! 1 in a complete financial market without the inclusion of weather
risk. There are two dates in the model for which the economy is
operated, now and then, i.e., =t 0 and 1. All of the uncertainties will
be resolved at time =t 1. All financial and operation decisions are
made now while all payoffs on those decisions will be received then. In
the standard complete financial market model, an economic state may
28
be interpreted as an index of economic conditions and it is assumed
that there are as many stock contracts, i.e., the basis stock, as there
are states of nature, and each basis stock contract pays one dollar in
a particular state and zero otherwise. A corporate stock may then be
interpreted as a portfolio of these basis stock contracts. It follows that
in a complete financial market, a corporate stock is a speculative risk.
The economy is composed of individual investors, who make
their investment portfolios to maximize the utility, and corporations
where there are managers, who make operation and financial
decisions on behalf of the shareholders. One simple interpretation of
the managers’ objective is to maximize the current shareholders’
market value. With the inclusion of weather risk, the otherwise
complete financial market becomes incomplete. In the economy
constructed with weather risk, the state space is expanded and the
weather index wz is incorporated. For simplicity, throughout this
dissertation, the weather index is assumed as heating-degree-days
(HDD), and a natural gas utility firm is the object firm being studied.
Therefore, “then” defined in this model may be interpreted as a winter
season.
With the inclusion of the weather index into the original model,
29
the state space is interpreted now as ∈ ×e w e w(z ,z ) Z Z . The variable ez
is interpreted as an index of economic conditions and = ωeZ [0, ] is the
set of these index numbers. The variable wz represents a weather
state and = υwZ [0, ]8 is the set of these states. Throughout this
dissertation, the weather index wz represents different HDDs in the
winter season. The weather risk is a speculative risk, i.e., weather-
related loss could be positive or negative. If it is positive, it means the
natural gas utility suffers a loss because of the weather condition, i.e.,
the HDDs are below the neutral level. If it is negative, it means the
firm gains from the weather conditions, i.e., the HDDs are above the
neutral level.
The corporate net payoff is represented as e w(q,z ,z )Π , including
the impacts from economic and weather conditions. The firm’s payoff
function is Π = −e wP(z ,z )q c(q) , where P is the unit price of the firm’s
product then, and c(q) is the cost function for a production level of q .
If the cost function is assumed convex, the corporate payoff is concave
30
8 This is the set of HDD values for the observation period. Based on the definition of
HDD in the first part (Introduction) of this chapter, the sum of the daily HDD
number over the observation period must be at least zero.
in production level. It is a competitive firm facing with price
uncertainty. The firm’s payoff function is satisfied with the principle of
increasing uncertainty (see Appendix).
Let +wZ and
−
wZ be the weather states that bring the positive and
negative loss to the firm respectively, i.e., +wZ represents lower HDDs
and −wZ represents higher HDDs at time t 1= . Let =
o 0
w wZ {z } be the
neutral weather state, i.e., the actual HDDs coincide with the forecast
of weather stations. Table 2 presents the components of this model.
Table 2
eZ Economic index set [0, ]ω
wZ Weather index set [0, ]υ
+
wZ Weather index set with positive loss
−
wZ Weather index set with negative “loss”
0
wz Neutral weather index
ez Individual economic index
wz Individual weather index9
waz HDD index used in weather derivative
k
wz Strike value selected by firm
Π Firm’s payoff function
q Firm’s production level
For the firm studied in this dissertation, a HDD put option is
31
used to hedge an unusually warm winter. If kwz is the strike HDD
value, and the measurement site in the weather derivative contract
has a HDD numerical value as waz over the observation period10, the
payoff of the weather derivative is = −kwa w waG(z ) I[max (z z ,0)] , where
−
k
w wamax (z z ,0) is the exercise value of weather derivative contract.
−
k
w waI[max (z z ,0)] is the industry standard dollar amount11 of this
exercise value. By using the industry standard dollar amount, and
measuring on the benchmark site12 instead of the exposure site, the
moral hazard and adverse selection problems are eliminated but the
basis risk13 is introduced.
32
9 In this dissertation, the weather index is the numerical sum of HDDs over the
observation period.
10 The weather risk exposure site, i.e., hedged site, may not be the same site where
the HDD in weather derivative contract was measured. The uncertainty of this
difference may be minimal, though. First, the utility firm is usually local, and a local
measurement site is available at airport or within the city. Even if it is not close to
the exposure site, there must be a strong HDD correlation between the
measurement site and exposure site, because both are within the same local city.
Second, the HDD difference may be minimized over the observation period if the
exposure and measurement sites are close and the period is long enough. Usually
the observation period in weather derivative contract is at least 30 days. Therefore,
the uncertainty of the HDD difference is negligible. A detailed discussion can be
found in Chapter IV.
11 An industry standard rebate eliminates the moral hazard problem. A plausible
way is to categorize firms into small, medium, and large operation size based on the
revenue history, and rebates to the hedged firm based on its category, the expected
economic condition and the ex post HDD value.
12 A benchmark site is usually highly reliable and has a long history of recording.
Usually it is sponsored by the government. Examples of benchmark measurement
sites are airports, central parks etc.
13 A detailed discussion of basis risk can be found in Chapter IV.
If the firm selects weather hedging and we let = e wz (z ,z ) , the
payoff becomes
Π +
= Π + −
wa
k
w wa
(q,z) G(z )
(q,z) I[max(z z ,0)]
(0.1)
If the weather derivative is exercised, the corporate payoff is
Π + −ke w w wa(q,z ,z ) I(z z ) (0.2)
With the absence of basis risk14, the firm would have recouped
its revenue loss due to negative weather conditions, by exercising the
weather derivative. Contrasted with the industry standard loss
−
k
w waI(z z ), the firm’s actual loss experience is
= Π − Πke w e wL (q,z ,z ) (q,z ,z ). In the absence of basis risk, ≡I L 15. The
value of the basis risk is −I L . If the weather derivative is in the
money, a swap may be used to eliminate the basis risk. The firm
exchanges the HDD put with the real loss experience less the swap
price p, i.e., −L p . If the swap price is less than the negative of basis
risk, i.e., < −p L I, it would be preferred.
33
14 Basis risk is the difference between the payoff of weather derivatives and the
actual loss experienced by the firm due to negative weather conditions.
The implications of basis risk will be discussed in Chapter IV.
For simplicity, it is assumed that ≡w waz z and ≡I L in this chapter
and the following Chapter III, i.e., basis risk is assumed absent.
Let B be the corporate leverage level. For an unhedged firm, the
net payoff then is Π − B . For a hedged firm, the net payoff then is
Π − +B W , where W is the rebate provided by the weather derivative,
i.e., = wW G(z ). With a risky leverage, firm has a probability of
insolvency. When the firm becomes insolvent, stock value is zero and
bondholder becomes the creditor of the firm16. To study the stock and
bond value of the firm, an iso-earning curve in the space of ×e wZ Z is
interpreted as below. To better analyze the firm’s economic behavior,
the firm’s payoff function Π is assumed to be well defined. That is, it
is continuously twice differentiable at each of its arguments ez and
wz (Continuity and Differentiability), and strictly increasing at each of
its arguments ez and wz , i.e.,
∂Π
>
∂ e
0
z
and ∂Π >
∂ w
0
z
(Monotonicity). In
addition, for each given production level q , the iso-earning curve
Π = c in the plane of ×e wZ Z is strictly rotund (convexity), i.e., if both
34
15 I is the payoff of the weather derivative, and L is the loss actually experienced by
the firm due to negative weather conditions.
=
1 1 1
e wz (z ,z ) and =
2 2 2
e wz (z ,z ) generate the same payoff c, any weighted
average of 1z and 2z must generate more payoff. It is noted that for
different level of earning, the iso-earning curves may have different
shapes in the plane of ×e wZ Z , though all strictly convex. For a given
leverage level B, the iso-earning curve17 may be interpreted by a
smooth and continuous convex curve as in Figure 118.
To better illustrate the figure, the notations are defined in Table
3.
35
16 It is assumed that bondholder is the only creditor for the firm if it is insolvent.
17 In Figure 1, the iso-earning curve Π = B is also the insolvency boundary line for
an unhedged firm.
18 It is noted that
∂
= − Π Π <
∂
e
w e
w
z
0
z
, and
∂
>
∂
2
e
2
w
z
0
z
by PIU, where Π = ∂Π ∂w wz and
Π = ∂Π ∂e ez .
Table 3
Figure 1 (See Appendix II) displays the iso-earning curve then,
after the production decision q was determined19. For each given q ,
the firm’s payoff Π is determined by = e wz (z ,z ) then. Principle of
Increasing Uncertainty gives the decreasing shape of each iso-earning
curve Π = c under all possible production decision q . Each
36
19 Figure 1 is an iso-earning curve then with given production level q . A well
maintained technology is implicitly assumed, and firm manager knows the location
1Θ
The sets when the weather put is exercised, i.e., the sets
× < ke w w wZ {z : z z }
2Θ
The sets when weather put is not exercised, i.e., the sets
× ≥ ke w w wZ {z : z z }
1A
Solvent states with negative weather condition, without using
weather derivative, i.e., the sets × Π > ∩ Θe w e w 1{z z : (z ,z ) B}
2A
Solvent states with neutral or positive weather condition, i.e., the
sets × Π > ∩ Θe w e w 2{z z : (z ,z ) B}
1aB
Insolvent states difference b/w using weather derivative and
without using weather derivative, under negative weather
conditions, i.e., the sets × Π < < Π + ∩ Θe w e w e w 1{z z : (z ,z ) B (z ,z ) W}
1bB
Insolvent states with using weather derivative, under negative
weather conditions, i.e., the sets × Π + < ∩ Θe w e w 1{z z : (z ,z ) W B}
2B
Insolvent states with neutral or positive weather condition, i.e., the
sets × Π < ∩ Θe w e w 2{z z : (z ,z ) B}
combination of e w(z ,z ) in the black convex curve represents the same
corporate payoff Π = B 20. The more corporate leverage level is, the
more upward the iso-earning curve has to move. It is because a better
economic condition and/or a more positive weather condition are/is
needed to keep solvent at a higher leverage level. It is noted that
different iso-earning curves under given production decision q may
have different shapes (elasticity), though all convex and decreasing.
The function format of Π e w(z ,z ) determines the shape21. For
unhedged firm, the iso-earning curve (insolvency boundary) is
Π = − =e w e w(z ,z ) P(z ,z )q c(q) B 22. For hedged firm, the iso-earning curve
(insolvency boundary) is Π + = Π Π =ke w e wW max[ (z ,z ), (z ,z )] B23.
In Figure 1, ∪1 2A A denotes the combination of economic and
weather states where the firm is solvent with a risky debt, without
using the weather derivative; ∪1 2B B denotes the condition in which
37
of production surface and his location on production surface with control of input
choice. Firm manager also knows the cost of each input choice.
20 It is noted that B was determined now, and payoff Π is realized then.
21 Let the iso-earning curve be =e wz g(z ) in Fig 1, different iso-earning curve yields
different function g such that Π =w w(g(z ), z ) B . In fact, =e B wz g (z ) may be used to
better interpret that function g is dependent on B.
22 Shown as the black curve in Fig 1.
23 Shown as the red curve in Fig 1. With the absence of basis risk, payoff of the
weather derivative recoups the loss due to negative weather conditions for the firm,
i.e., = − = = Π − Πk kw w e w e wW I(z z ) L (q,z ,z ) (q,z ,z ) when it is exercised.
firm is insolvent without using the weather derivative. Θ1 represents
the combination of the states on which the weather derivative contract
can be written. If weather derivative is used, the insolvency boundary
line is dropped to the red line shown in Figure 124, and the insolvency
states can be interpreted by 1b 2B B∪ . Therefore, by using weather
derivatives, the insolvency probability is reduced.
2.3 Valuation of Weather Derivative
One of the fundamental problems on weather derivative is its
valuation. With a non-tradable underlying “asset”, the traditional
financial valuation technique for derivatives cannot be applied.
Actuarial technique, which is widely used as an insurance pricing
paradigm, may not well hold to price weather derivative, either. This
section is an attempt to price the weather derivative on the extended
basic model.
In our economy, there are two agents in the market: real risk-
38
24 It is because within Θ1 , i.e., weather derivative is exercised since < kw wz z , the
firm’s payoff becomes Π + = Π ke wW (z ,z ) . At the iso-earning curve as well as the
insolvency boundary line Π + =e w(z ,z ) W B for the hedged firm, there must be a
averse individual agents and the fiduciary agents for the
corporations25. The economy has two independent risks, which can be
characterized by weather states ∈w wz Z , and economic states ∈e ez Z .
The state set is expanded to ∈ ×e w e w(z ,z ) Z Z .
The standard finance literature assumes the existence of basis
stock in a complete market. The inclusion of weather risk makes the
market incomplete. If the firm does not hedge the weather risk, the
risk-averse investors will find a way to hedge it.
Consider purchasing put and call option portfolios in the
following way: Investors can go long in corporate stock and put
options, and go short in the call options at the same time. If the
exercise price in both puts and calls is fixed at E , the put has a value
as − Πmax[0,E ], and the call has a value as Π −max[0, E]. The
portfolio has a value as Π + − Π − Π − =max[0,E ] max[0, E] E . For each
given wz , the firm’s payoff may be interpreted by the various straight
lines (black ones) in Figure 2 (See Appendix II)26. For each given ez ,
39
unique = ke B wz g (z ) to define the insolvency boundary line as the red line in Fig 1.
This is due to the monotonicity of the firm’s payoff function Π .
25 It is not necessary to introduce another fiduciary agent in the economy. However,
it makes the model explicitly clear with the introduction of fiduciary agent.
26 It is due to the monotonicity of Π , i.e., Π >e 0 .
*
w ez (z ) is defined as the risk-adjusted weather state, i.e.,
Π = Π∫
w
*
e w w e w wZ
(z ,z ) f(z ) (z ,z )dZ 27. The straight line (red one28) in Figure
2 displays the payoff function Π *e w e[z ,z (z )] .
If the option strike price is set as = Π = Π*e w eE (z ,z ) E( z ) for each
economic index ez , it follows by Jensen’s inequality29 that, this
hedging portfolio is preferred by risk-averse investors.
This hedging behavior allows a simple interpretation of the
stock value for the unhedged firm. Let ep(z ) be the basis stock price
now which will pay one dollar then in state ez and zero otherwise and
assume such a basis stock exists30. The hedged31 payoff on corporate
stock on the contingency of economic index ez is Π = Π
*
e w e(z ,z ) E( z ).
40
27 In this definition, wf(z ) is the density function.
*
wz is an economic risk-adjusted
weather index. Although wz and ez are independent,
*
wz is generally dependent on
ez , i.e., for different ez ,
*
wz may be different.
28 For simplicity, Π *e w e[z ,z (z )] is displayed as a straight red line. Since
*
wz is
generally dependent on ez , Π
*
e w e[z ,z (z )]may be a curved line instead of a straight
line.
29 Jensen’s inequality indicates that for risk-averse utility functions, E[u(c)] u[E(c)]< .
In our framework, it means Π < Πe eE[u( z )] u[E( z )] .
30 This assumption holds because of the independence of ez and wz .
31 If the firm is unhedged, risk-averse investors prefer to hedge the weather risk on
their own accounts.
This is because all individual investors are assumed risk-averse in the
financial market. By holding the portfolios discussed earlier, investors
gain more utility. Since there are only real agents, i.e., individual
investors, and fictitious agents, i.e., fiduciaries for the firms, in the
market, the payoff on corporate stock becomes Π = Π*e w e(z ,z ) E( z )
when all risk-averse investors hold the same portfolio.
The unhedged firm’s stock value is then interpreted as
Θ
= Π
= Π
= Π
∫
∫ ∫
∫∫
e
e w
u *
e e w eZ
e w e w w eZ Z
w e e w e w
S p(z ) (z ,z )dz
p(z )[ f(z ) (z ,z )dz ]dz
f(z )p(z ) (z ,z )dz dz
(0.3)
These results are summarized in the following proposition.
Proposition 1:
Assume the independence of the weather index and the
economic index32, an unhedged firm has a stock value as
Θ
ω υ
= Π
= Π
∫∫
∫ ∫
u
w e e w e w
w e e w e w0 0
S f(z )p(z ) (z ,z )dz dz
f(z )p(z ) (z ,z )dz dz
41
32 Though weather conditions may have an impact on the economic index, the
impact may be negligible. Two reasons may explain this: First, a certain weather
condition may have negative impacts on some firms, but may be positive on other
segments of the economy. Second, economic conditions may be more affected by
other factors, such as notional GDP, financial markets, unemployment rates etc,
making them less dependent on weather conditions.
Proof:
See above results.
QED
Fiduciary for the firm can also hedge on the corporate account
by using weather derivatives. Assume that the strike index value in
the weather derivative is set at kwz , the hedged firm’s payoff is
υ
υ
= − + Π + Π − Π
= − + Π Π
∫ ∫
∫ ∫
e
e
h k k
e w e w e w e w w eZ 0
k k
e w e w e w w eZ 0
S P p(z ){ f(z )[ (z ,z ) max(0, (z ,z ) (z ,z ))]dz }dz
P p(z ){ f(z )max[ (z ,z ), (z ,z )]dz }dz
where kP is the price of weather put with a strike value as kwz .
The no arbitrage principle shows that the unhedged firm has
the same stock value as the hedged firm. Equivalently, it sets the
value of weather derivative as
υ
ω υ
ω υ
Θ
= Π + Π − Π
− Π
= Π − Π
=
∫ ∫
∫ ∫
∫ ∫
∫∫
e
1
k k
e w w w w w eZ 0
w e e w e w0 0
k
w e w w e w0 0
w e w w e
P p(z ){ f(z )[ (z ) max(0, (z ) (z ))]dz }dz
f(z )p(z ) (z ,z )dz dz
f(z )p(z )max[0, (z ) (z )]dz dz
f(z )p(z )G(z )dz dz
(0.4)
42
That is, the price of weather derivatives must be equal to the
risk-adjusted future payoff of the derivative. The above pricing
formula implicitly combines the actuarial technique33 and financial
paradigm34. This valuation stands in the economic model constructed
here.
Other hedging strategies exist. Suppose the firm goes long in a
set of put options with exercise price at Π 0e w(z ,z ) at each economic
state ez , where
0
wz is the ‘neutral” weather state defined in Table 2.
The payoff for that set of put options is Π − Π0e w e wmax[ (z ,z ) (z ,z ),0] on
the contingency of economic state ez . It follows that the price for the
set of put options is
Θ
Π − Π∫∫ 0w e e w e w e wf(z )p(z )max[ (z ,z ) (z ,z ),0]dz dz . If the
strike value in the weather derivative is also set at 0wz , it duplicates
the set of put options. Therefore, there is an efficient gain by the
inclusion of weather derivative in the financial market. These results
are summarized as the following proposition.
43
33 The actuarial technique is implicitly included in the probability distribution of the
weather index, i.e., the density function as wf(z ) .
34 The financial paradigm is implicitly included in the price of basis stock for each
economic index, i.e., ep(z ) .
Proposition 2:
For a weather derivative with strike value at kwz , its price is
interpreted as
ω ._.free scenario, and makes forward contract more preferable.
Scenario 2
If the firm’s leverage level is Π ≤ ≤ Πq oe w(z ,0) B (0,z ), the iso-
earning curve for corporate payoff function may be displayed as the
Figure 13 (See Appendix II).
96
For the first component of basis risk, it follows that ∂ <
∂
V 0
c
, the
same as shown in Scenario 1. The implication of second component of
basis risk is not unambiguous. The presence of basis risk does not
make weather derivative less preferable compared with forward in this
case. This is because weather derivative still provides a positive payoff
to the hedged firm under negative weather conditions, which is
irrelevant with the presence or absence of basis risk. Forward
contracts generally cannot reduce the insolvency probability
unambiguously as weather derivative can in this scenario. Therefore,
the presence of basis risk may diminish part of the positive role that
an otherwise basis risk-free weather derivative does, it does not
reverse to such a level that makes weather derivative less preferable.
When there is probability of insolvency with the presence of
basis risk, hedging with weather derivative is still optimal, but
hedging with forward is not optimal. If weather derivative has been
used, hedging with additional forward is not optimal.
97
Scenario 3
In Scenario 3, firm’s leverage level B increases to
o f o
w e w(0,z ) B (z ,z )Π < ≤ Π , where
f
ez is implicitly defined as
f o
e wf P(z ,z )= . It
may be interpreted by Figure 14 (See Appendix II) with the presence of
basis risk.
For the first component of basis risk, it follows that ∂ <
∂
V 0
c
, the
same as shown in Scenario 1 and 2. The implication of second
component of basis risk is not unambiguous though. With similar
arguments as did in Scenario 2, the presence of basis risk does not
make weather derivative less preferable compared with forward in this
case. The presence of basis risk may reduce part of the positive role
that an otherwise basis risk-free weather derivative does, it does not
reverse to such a level that makes weather derivative less preferable.
Addition of forward contract adds additional value to the firm, which
follows from
υ
=
∂ ∂ ∂Π
= >
∂ ∂ ∂∫ ∫
w
hw
k(z )
e w e wq q 0 0
V q p(z )f(z ) dz dz 0
n n q
. .
Therefore, hedging with weather derivative is still optimal, but
hedging with forward is not optimal. If weather derivative has been
used, hedging with additional forward further increases the firm’s
98
value.
Scenario 4
In this Scenario, the corporate leverage level is increased to
f o o
e w w(z ,z ) B ( ,z )Π < ≤ Π ω . The presence of basis risk may be illustrated by
Figure 15 (See Appendix II).
For the first component of basis risk, it follows that ∂ <
∂
V 0
c
, the
same as shown in Scenario 1. The implication of second component of
basis risk is not unambiguous though. With similar arguments as did
in previous scenarios, the presence of basis risk does not make
weather derivative less preferable compared with forward in this case.
The presence of basis risk may reduce part of the positive role that an
otherwise basis risk-free weather derivative does, it does not reverse
to such a level that makes weather derivative less preferable. If
forward is already used, addition of weather derivative adds additional
value to the firm, which follows from
υ
=
∂ ∂ ∂Π
= >
∂ ∂ ∂∫ ∫
w
hf
h(z )
e w e wk kq q 0 0
w w
V q p(z )f(z ) dz dz 0
z z q
. .
While there is basis risk, hedging with weather derivative is still
optimal compared with forward. Hedging with forward is not optimal.
99
If forward has been used, hedging with additional weather derivative
will further improve the corporate value, but may not outperform the
single use of weather derivative as a hedging instrument. The
presence of basis risk may reduce or increase the positive role that
weather derivative provides in hedging, however, the weather
derivative still reduces the insolvency probability unambiguously.
Scenario 5
In this scenario, the corporate leverage level is increased to
o P
w e( ,z ) B (z , )Π ω < ≤ Π υ 68, where
P
ez is implicitly defined as
P
eP(z , ) fυ = .
The inclusion of basis risk was interpreted by Figure 16 (See Appendix
II).
When the firm’s leverage level comes to this high, weather
derivative with a strike value =k 0w wz z cannot reduce the insolvency
probability, and no firm’s value is preserved. The presence of basis
risk may reduce the insolvency probability, if c is negative enough. It
follows from ∂ <
∂
V 0
c
. However, this implication is not unambiguous.
Forward contract alone neither provides positive role in preserving
100
corporate value.
While there is probability of insolvency, hedging with weather
derivative is not optimal69, neither is hedging with forward. If forward
has been used, hedging with additional weather derivative will not
improve the corporate value, neither the opposite case, under the
presence of basis risk.
Scenario 6
In this scenario, the corporate leverage level is increased to
P
e(z , ) B ( , )Π υ < ≤ Π ω υ , where
P
ez is implicitly defined as
P
eP(z , ) fυ = . The
presence of basis risk may be interpreted by Figure 17 (See Appendix
II).
When the firm’s leverage level comes to this high, weather
derivative with a strike value =k 0w wz z cannot reduce the insolvency
probability, and no firm’s value is preserved. The presence of basis
risk may reduce the insolvency probability, if c is negative enough. It
follows from ∂ <
∂
V 0
c
. However, this implication is not unambiguous.
101
68 While this may not be guaranteed to hold, the exceptions will be discussed in the
following scenarios.
The presence of basis risk cannot generally provide positive incentives
for firm’s managers to preserve more value70. Forward contract
provides negative role in preserving corporate value, and more
insolvency probability is introduced.
In Scenario 5, the corporate leverage level is set as
o P
w e( , z ) B (z , )Π ω < ≤ Π υ , which may not hold always. One exception is as
the following Figure 18 (See Appendix II).
It is noted that forward contract plays a negative role, and
weather derivative does provide less insolvency possibility. The
presence of basis risk may reduce or increase the insolvency
probability that weather derivative already reduced, but cannot
eliminate the positive role of weather derivative. That is, with the
presence of basis risk, weather derivative still provides a rebate under
negative weather conditions, which reduces the insolvency probability
as shown in Figure 18. If weather derivative is coupled with a forward,
it is noted that
102
69 Unless the strike value of weather derivative is increased to >k 0w wz z .
hw
w
e w e wq q 0 0
k(z )
e w e w0 0
V q p(z )f(z ) dz dz
n n q
q p(z )f(z ) dz dz
n q
0
υ ω
=
υ
∂ ∂ ∂Π
=
∂ ∂ ∂
∂ ∂Π
=
∂ ∂
<
∫ ∫
∫ ∫ (1.3)
Therefore, addition of forward will diminish the positive role
that weather derivative already provides, and not preferable. Weather
derivative alone provides the optimal hedging contract set.
The following table summarizes the optimal contract set for
hedging the weather risk, and achieve the most efficient allocation of
resource, with the presence of basis risk.
Table 9: Impacts of hedging portfolio with the presence of basis risk
Scenario Forward Weather Derivative Both included
1 Positive (Best) Positive Positive
2 Neutral Positive Positive
3 Neutral Positive Positive (Best)
4 Neutral Positive Neutral
5 Neutral Neutral Neutral
6 Negative Neutral Negative
6b Negative Positive Neutral
In general, the presence of basis risk does not make the weather
derivative less desirable, except the scenario 1. It is quite intuitive. By
103
70 When the corporate leverage level comes to this high level, the rebate provided by
weather derivative under negative weather conditions cannot reduce the insolvency
probability, and preserve corporate value.
providing a rebate to the firm under negative weather conditions,
weather derivative still outperforms forward in most of the scenarios.
The presence of basis risk makes the rebate more or less than the
firm actually desires, but this impact cannot change the basic
function of weather derivative.
With the presence of basis risk, weather derivative still provides
a more holistic hedging in most of the scenarios, yet the rebate is
more uncertain, i.e., more or less than the firm actually desires. While
basis risk seems innocuous in most of the scenarios, it does hamper
the positive hedging role provided by weather derivative, for instance,
in Scenario 1. The corporate value preserved by weather derivative
may be reduced in scenario 1, therefore makes it less desirable. This
is consistent with some recent empirical research which demonstrates
a strong incentive for the firm manager to select a hedging portfolio
with little basis risk [c.f.. Haushalter (2000)], because Scenario 1
represents a low corporate leverage level, which may be seen in many
firms.
In the presence of basis risk, this chapter has demonstrated
that it is optimal to hedge against the basis loss, and the less the
104
basis difference is, the better the hedging instrument will be preferred
by the risk-averse firm managers. The results are consistent with
recent empirical studies in the oil and gas industries, which
document strong incentives to hedge for large companies and
companies which have little basis risk.
105
Figure A
: G
as Price v.s. Season
A
ppendix I
Figures
H
enryH
ub G
as Price v.s. Tim
e
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18
8/31/1995
11/30/1995
2/29/1996
5/31/1996
8/31/1996
11/30/1996
2/28/1997
5/31/1997
8/31/1997
11/30/1997
2/28/1998
5/31/1998
8/31/1998
11/30/1998
2/28/1999
5/31/1999
8/31/1999
11/30/1999
2/29/2000
5/31/2000
8/31/2000
11/30/2000
2/28/2001
Tim
e Points
Price Index
H
igh Price
Low
Price
106
ez
0
+
wZ wZ
−
o
wz
υ
ω
1A
2A
1aB
2B
Θ1 Θ2
Π − =
Π + − =
B 0
( W B 0)
Π + − =
=
k 0
w w
W B 0
(z z )
Π − >B 0
Π
Π
Figure 1
Displays the a as for which firm is in the sol or insolvent states
Π − =B 0
1bB
1B
>k 0w wz z
<k 0w wz z
107 wzventre
ez
e(z , )Π υ
e(z ,0)Π
Π *e w e[z ,z (z )]
Π
Figure 2: Corporate payoff structure
10
8
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =
ez
wz
109
Figure 3: Compare different iso-earning curves in the surface
ez
ω
=P f
Π − =B 0=n q
Π − + =B W 0
Π − + − =B n(f P) 0
wz υ
Figure 4: Compare different iso-earning curves
110
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =ez
wz υ
ω
o
wz
n q=
n 0=
W B 0Π + − =
0 n q< <
A
111
Figure 5: Compare different iso-earning curves
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
ω
o
wz
W B 0Π + − =
B W n(f P) 0Π − + + − =
112
Figure 6: Compare different iso-earning curves wz υ
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
wz υ
ω
o
wz
W B 0Π + − =
B W n(f P)Π − + + −
113
Figure 7: Compare different iso-earning curves
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
wz υ
ω
o
wz
114
Figure 8: Compare different iso-earning curves
o
w wz z=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
ω
o
wz
115
Figure 9: Compare different iso-ea
o
w wz z=P f=
wz υ
rning curves
B W 0Π − + =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
ω
o
wz
B W n(f P) 0Π − + + − =
B 0Π − =
116
Figure 10: Compare different iso-ea
o
w wz z=P f=
wz υ
rning curves
ez
0
+
wZ wZ
−
0
wz
υ
ω
1A
2A
2B
Θ1 Θ2
Π −
Π +
B 0
( W
Π + − =
=
k 0
w w
W B 0
(z z )
Π − >B 0
Π
Π
Figure 11
Displays the insolvency boundaries when basis risk is present
Π − =B 0
>c 0
<c 0
=c 0
117 =wz
− =B 0)
ez
ω
=P f
Π − =B 0=n q
Π − + =B W 0
Π − + − =B n(f P) 0
wz υ 0
wz
Figure 12: Compare different iso-earning curves with basis risk
118
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =ez
wz υ
ω
o
wz
n q=
n 0=
W B 0Π + − =
0 n q< <
A
119
Figure 13: Compare different iso-earning curves with basis risk
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
wz υ
ω
o
wz
W B 0Π + − =
B W n(f P) 0Π − + + − =
120
Figure 14: Compare different iso-earning curves
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
ω
o
wz
W B 0Π + − =
B W n(f P)Π − + + −
121
Figure 15: Compare different iso-earning curves wz υ
P f=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
wz υ
ω
o
wz
122
Figure 16: Compare different iso-earning curves
o
w wz z=
B 0Π − =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
ω
o
wz
123
Figure 17: Compare different iso-ea
o
w wz z=P f=
wz υ
rning curves
P f=
B W 0Π − + =
B n(f P) 0Π − + − =e
z
wz υ
ω
o
wz
B W n(f P) 0Π − + + − =
B 0Π − =
124
Figure 18: Compare different iso-earning curves
o
w wz z=
Appendix II
Extensions of Principle of Increasing Uncertainty
The risk aversion nature of the firm has been studied in several
articles. It is widely believed that a risk adverse entrepreneur will
select the optimal level of output where the expected unit price is the
sum of marginal cost and the marginal risk premium. Both the
demand uncertainty and supply uncertainty of firm have been
extensively studied in the past literature. One of the representative
works on the production decision given demand uncertainty is Leland
(1972), where the principle of increasing uncertainty given demand
uncertainty has been introduced and discussed. MacMinn and
Holtmann complemented and generalized this work on the theory of
firm by investigating the effect of technological uncertainty on the
entrepreneur’s decision of optimal production level. Both models
generate the same optimality condition, namely the expected marginal
productivity equals the factor price, the marginal cost plus the
marginal risk premium. MacMinn and Holtmann’s work further
concluded that the sign of the marginal risk premium was not always
125
positive, as assumed in most of the literature, and it was dependent
on the structure of the firm’s technology function. With different
technology functions, the firm’s optimal decision would be different.
In MacMinn and Holtmann’s work, the single risk averse71
nature of the entrepreneur was not enough to yield one of the general
results in the theory of the firm: the optimal production level for a risk
averse entrepreneur was always less than that of a risk neutral
entrepreneur, unless the Principle of Increasing Uncertainty (PIU) also
holds. The model presented in their work is a single owner-
entrepreneur who makes the production decision, where the notion of
technological uncertainty may be interpreted in distinct ways.
Nonetheless, the technology is not well specified, due to the
uncertainty in their model, which yields the uncertainty in the
production and profit functions, and an increase of technological
uncertainty will increase the risk of production and therefore, the
profit distribution.
In the economic and finance literature, the technological
uncertainty is specified only by one non-negative continuous random
variable. The Principle of Increasing (Decreasing) Uncertainty was
126
derived under this single stochastic input framework. This may not be
always the case for the firm. For instance, for a firm that produces
energy products like electricity or natural gas, its optimal production
decision will be generally impacted by several stochastic variables,
such as economic conditions, weather conditions, and credit
conditions of energy marketers. Some of those variables will be
independent. For example, it is possible that economic conditions and
weather conditions may not be possibly dependent with each other,
and others will be dependent. For instance, the general economic
conditions may have an impact on the credit conditions of the energy
marketers. With the introduction of new risk hedging products from
the development of financial engineering, such as weather derivatives,
it is necessary to have a more generalized model, which includes
multiple stochastic variables to better interpret the firm’s
technological uncertainty.
In this chapter, an expanded model was conducted in which the
entrepreneur selects one input and shows what impact technological
uncertainty has on the firm’s scale of operation. Differing from the
existing literature, this model includes two stochastic variables, both
127
71 Risk averse nature mentioned here implicitly defined the nature of utility function
of which inject the risk into the firm’s technology.
To introduce the technological uncertainty, let 1Z , 2Z be two
non-negative continuous random variables. Let iΨ be their
distribution functions and iψ be their density functions, where
i 1,2= . The mean and variance of these two variables are
iz i i i0
z d (z )
∞
µ = Ψ∫
and
i i
2 2
z i z i0
(z ) d
∞
σ = − µ Ψ∫
Let the firm’s production function be 1 2F(x,z ,z ) where x is the
quantity of the nonstochastic input. Therefore, the firm’s output is a
random variable 1 2Y F(x,z ,z )= . Let the marginal productivity of
nonstochastic input be positive, i.e., x
FF 0
x
∂
= >
∂
and let the
production function be concave in x , i.e., xxF 0< . The firm’s profit is a
random variable 1 2 1 2(x,z ,z ) F(x,z ,z ) c(x)Π = − , where c(x) is the cost
function. An increase of riskiness in either 1Z or 2Z or a combination
of 1 2(Z ,Z ) will have an impact on the riskiness of both the production
function Y and profit function Π . However, whether the impact
128
for the firm’s entrepreneur.
increases or decreases the riskiness of the production and profit
functions is not clear in this extended model with more than one
stochastic input variable. The purpose of this chapter is to extend and
generalize the theory of the firm given more than one stochastic
variable in the firm’s production function, in particular, to study how
well the PIU or PDU principle may hold in this extended model.
Assume that the firm’s objective is to maximize the expected
utility of profit. Let u : →! ! be firm’s utility function and u'' 0 u'≤ < .
Let 1 2(z ,z )ψ be the joint density function for the distribution of 1 2(z ,z ).
The expected utility may be interpreted as H : →! ! by
1 2 1 2 1 20 0H(x) u[ (x,z ,z )] (z ,z )dz dz
∞ ∞
= Π ψ∫ ∫
If the cost function is linear, i.e., c(x) wx= , it may be noted that
H is a well-defined concave function. To interpret it, simply note that
2
xx xx x 1 2 1 20 0
H [u' u''( ) ] (z ,z )dz dz
0
∞ ∞
= Π + Π ψ
<
∫ ∫
The first order condition yields that
x x 1 2 1 2 1 20 0H u'( )[F (x,z ,z ) c '(x)] (z ,z )dz dz
0
∞ ∞
= Π − ψ
=
∫ ∫
129
The FOC may also be interpreted as
x 1 2 x 1 2E[F (x,z ,z )] c '(x) [ Cov(u'( ),F (x,z ,z ))/E(u')]= + − Π
The second term of RHS is the marginal risk premium in this
extended model with two stochastic variables. It follows that if the
marginal risk premium is positive (negative), the expected marginal
value product will be greater (less) than the marginal cost product. It
is clear that a single risk averse nature of the utility function cannot
determine the sign of marginal risk premium. It is also noted that the
sign of the covariance term is dependent on the relationship between
the profit function Π and the marginal value product function xF ,
since E(u') 0> due to the risk averse nature of the entrepreneur’s
utility function.
To show the effect on MRP of the sign of the covariance term of
the above first order condition, all the possibilities were listed below in
Table A1 and Table A2.
130
MRP
1z
F
1xz
F
2z
F
2xz
F
1 2(z z )
F
1 2x(z z )
F
+ + + + + + +
? + + + + + -
? + + + + - +
+ + + + + - -
? + + + - + +
? + + + - + -
? + + + - - +
? + + + - - -
? + + - + + +
? + + - + + -
? + + - + - +
? + + - + - -
+ + + - - + +
? + + - - + -
? + + - - - +
+ + + - - - -
? + - + + + +
? + - + + + -
? + - + + - +
? + - + + - -
? + - + - + +
- + - + - + -
- + - + - - +
? + - + - - -
? + - - + + +
- + - - + + -
- + - - + - +
? + - - + - -
? + - - - + +
? + - - - + -
? + - - - - +
? + - - - - -
(Table A1)
*MRP refers to the sign of Marginal Risk Premium
131
MRP
1z
F
1xz
F
2z
F
2xz
F
1 2(z z )
F
1 2x(z z )
F
? - + + + + +
? - + + + + -
? - + + + - +
? - + + + - -
? - + + - + +
- - + + - + -
- - + + - - +
? - + + - - -
? - + - + + +
- - + - + + -
- - + - + - +
? - + - + - -
? - + - - + +
? - + - - + -
? - + - - - +
? - + - - - -
+ - - + + + +
? - - + + + -
? - - + + - +
+ - - + + - -
? - - + - + +
? - - + - + -
? - - + - - +
? - - + - - -
? - - - + + +
? - - - + + -
? - - - + - +
? - - - + - -
+ - - - - + +
? - - - - + -
? - - - - - +
+ - - - - - -
(Table A2)
*MRP refers to the sign of Marginal Risk Premium
132
It should be noted that the sign of marginal risk premium
depends on the sign of the covariance term, which comes from the
relationship between Π and xF . A sufficient condition for a positive
marginal risk premium is that
1 1z xz
F 0Π > AND
2 2z xz
F 0Π > AND
1 2 1 2z z x(z z )
F 0Π > , since
ii
zz
F (i 1,2)= Π = and
1 2 1 2z z z z
F = Π . Table 1 gives all
of the possible 62 64= conditions, of which 16 possibilities will yield a
clear sign of marginal risk premium, i.e., either positive or negative
MRP. The other 48 possibilities will not unambiguously yield the sign
of the marginal risk premium, therefore, will not give a clear
conclusion on technological uncertainty. It should also be noted that
the PIU condition concluded here, i.e.,
1 1z xz
F 0Π > ,
2 2z xz
F 0Π > and
1 2 1 2z z x(z z )
F 0Π > does not require the independence of stochastic inputs
1z and 2z , therefore may apply to the general uncertainty scenarios.
From the first order condition, it is clear that a positive
marginal risk premium mandates the nature of risk aversion and the
PIU assumptions. It follows that a risk averse entrepreneur would
make less production under the uncertainty scenario other than the
certainty scenario. The more risk averse the entrepreneur is, the less
133
the production level would be. The proof (not shown) follows from the
definition of riskiness by Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) and the work
by MacMinn and Holtmann (1983).
134
Reference
Arrow, K. J. (1965). Aspects of the Theory of Risk Bearing, Helsinki:
Johnsonin Saatie.
Arrow, K. J. (1974a). Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing, North
Holland.
Arrow, K. J. (1974b). “Optimal Insurance and Generalized
Deductibles.” Scandinavian Actuarial Journal 1-42.
Binswanger, M. and H. Wealth (1993). “Wealth, Weather Risk and the
Composition and Profitability of Agricultural Investments.”
Economics Journal 103 (416): 56-78.
Bowers, J. and G. Mould (1994). “Weather Risk in Offshore Projects.”
Journal of the Operational Research Society 45 (4): 409-18.
Brockett, P. L. and Y. Kahane (1992). “Risk, Return, Skewness and
Preference.” Management Science 851-66.
Brockett, P. L. and J. Garven (1999). “ A Reexamination of the
relationship Between Utility Functions, Risk Preference, and
Moment Orderings.” Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance
135
D’Arcy, S. and N.A. Doherty (1988). “Financial Theory of Pricing
Property-Liability Insurance Contracts”, 1988, Philadelphia:
S.S. Huebner Foundation.
D’Arcy, S. and J.R. Garven (1990). “Property-Liability Insurance
Pricing Models: An Empirical Evaluation”, Journal of Risk and
Insurance, July 1990, pp.391-430
Doherty, N.A. (1981). “A Portfolio Theory of Insurance Capacity”,
Journal of Risk and Insurance, 1981, pp. 405-420
Doherty, N.A.(1984). “Portfolio Efficient buying strategies”, Journal of
Risk and Insurance, 1984, pp. 205-224
Doherty, N. and J.R. Garven (1986). “Price Regulation in Property-
Liability insurance: A Contingent Claim Approach”, Journal of
Finance, 1986, pp.1031-1050
Doherty, N. and H. Schlesinger (1983a). “Optimal Insurance in
Incomplete Markets”, Journal of Political Economy, 1983a,
pp.1045-1054.
Doherty, N. and H. Schlesinger (1983b). “The Optimal Deductible for
an Insurance Policy when Initial Wealth is Random”, Journal of
Business, 56, 1983b, pp.555-565.
136
Froot, K. A. (1999). “The Evolving Market for Catastrophic Event
Risk.” Risk Management and Insurance Review Volume II (3): 1-
28.
Green, R. C. (1984). “Investment Incentives, Debt and Warrants.”
Journal of Financial Economics 13: 115-36.
Haushalter, G. (2000). “Financing Policy, Basis Risk, and Corporate
Hedging: Evidence from Oil and Gas Producers.” Journal of
Finance 55 (1): 107-52.
Jensen, M. and C. Smith (1985). “Stockholder, Manager, and Creditor
Interests: Applications of Agency Theory.” Recent Advances in
Corporate Finance. E. Altman and M. Subrahmanayam,
Richard D. Irwin.
Jensen, M. and W. Meckling (1976). “Theory of the Firm: Managerial
Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of
Financial Economics 3: 305-60.
Leggio, K. and D. Lien (2000). “Hedging Gas Bills with Weather
Derivatives.” University of Kansas.
137
Leland, H. E. (1970). “Theory of the Firm Facing Uncertain Demand.”
Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences,
Stanford University, Tech. Report No. 24. Jan. 1970.
Leland, H. E. (1972a). “Theory of the Firm Facing Uncertain Demand.”
American Economic Review 62: 278-91.
Leland, H. E. (1972b). “On the Existence of Optimal Policies under
Uncertainty.” Journal of Economic Theory 4: 35-44.
Leland, H. E. (1978). “Information, Managerial Choice and
Stockholder Unanimity.” Review of Economic Studies 45 (3):
527-43.
MacMinn, R. D. and A, Holtmann (1983). “Technological Uncertainty
and the Theory of the Firm.” Southern Economic Journal 50:
120-36.
MacMinn, R. D. (1987a). “Forward Markets, Stock Markets, and the
Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Finance 42(5): 1167-85.
MacMinn, R. D. (1987b). “ Insurance and Corporate Risk
Management.” Journal of Risk and Insurance 54(4): 658-77.
MacMinn, R. (1989) “Limited Liability, Corporate Objectives and
Management Decisions” Working Paper, University of Texas.
138
MacMinn, R. D. and F. H. Page (1991). “Stock Options and the
Corporate Objective Function.” Working Paper, University of
Texas at Austin.
MacMinn, R. D. (1993a). “On the Risk Shifting Problem and
Convertible Bonds.” Advances in Quantitative Analysis of
Finance and Accounting.
MacMinn, R. D. and J. Garven (1993b). “The Under-investment
Problem, Bond Covenants and Insurance.” Journal of Risk and
Insurance 60(4): 635-45.
MacMinn, R. D. (1999). “On Corporate Risk Management and
Insurance.” Working Paper, University of Texas at Austin.
MacMinn, R. D. (2000). “Risk and Choice: A Perspective on the
Integration of Finance and Insurance.” Risk Management and
Insurance Review.
Mayers, D. and C. Smith (1982). “On the Corporate Demand for
Insurance.” Journal of Business 55: 281-96.
Mayers, D. and C. W. Smith Jr. (1983). “The Interdependence of
Individual Portfolio Decisions and the Demand for Insurance”,
Journal of Political Economy, April 1983, pp.304-11
139
Mayers, D. and C. W. Smith Jr. (1994). “Managerial discretion,
regulation, and stock insurer ownership structure”, Journal of
Risk and Insurance, December 1994, pp.638-55
Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1958). “The Cost of Capital,
Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment.” American
Economic Review Vol. XLVIII (3): 261-97.
Muller A. and M. Grandi (2000). “Weather Derivatives: A Risk
Management Tool for Weather-sensitive Industries.” Geneva
Papers on Risk and Insurance 25 (2): 273-87.
Pratt, J. W. (1964). “Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large.”
Econometrica 32: 122-36.
Richter, R. (1998) “Temperature, price and profit: Managing weather
risk.” Public Utilities Fortnightly 136(16):40-49.
Rothschild, M. and J. E. Stiglitz (1970). “Increasing Risk: I. A
Definition.” Journal of Economic Theory 2: 225-43.
Schlesinger, H. (1983a). “Optimal Insurance in Incomplete Markets.”
Journal of Political Economy 1045-54.
Schlesinger, H. (1983b). “The Optimal Deductible for an Insurance
Policy when Initial Wealth is Random.” Journal of Business 56:
555-65.
140
Smith, C. W. and R. M. Stulz (1985). “The Determinants of Firms’
Hedging Policies.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 20 (4): 391-405.
Stulz, R. M. (1984). “Optimal Hedging Policies.” Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis 19 (2): 127-40.
Stulz, R. M. (1996). “Rethinking Risk Management.” Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance (Fall): 8-24.
Zolkos, R. (2000). “Forecast calls for growth in weather risk
securitization.” Business Insurance 34 (5): 3-22.
141
Vita
Mulong Wang was born in the County of Funing, Jiangsu
Province of China on April 5, 1976, the youngest son of Dongmei Mao
and Minxuan Wang. After completing his work in Suzhou high school,
he entered the University of Science and Technology of China in 1991
and received his B.S. in 1996. He came to the University of Texas at
Austin in 1997 as a Ph.D. student in the Department of Management
Science and Information Systems.
Permanent Address: Room 20-103, GuiHua XinChun,
Suzhou, Jiangsu, China, 215006
This dissertation was typed by the author.
142
._.
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- CH1061.pdf