Copyright
by
Somchai Supattarakul
2003
The Dissertation Committee for Somchai Supattarakul Certifies that this is
the approved version of the following dissertation:
Earnings Warnings:
Market Reaction and Management Motivation
Committee:
Rowland K. Atiase, Supervisor
Robert N. Freeman
Tom S. Shively
Laura T. Starks
Senyo Y. Tse
Earnings Warnings:
Market Reaction and Management Motivation
by
Somchai Supattarakul, B.B.A., M.B.A., M.P.A.
Dissertation
Presented
114 trang |
Chia sẻ: huyen82 | Lượt xem: 1587 | Lượt tải: 0
Tóm tắt tài liệu Earnings Warnings: Market Reaction and Management Motivation, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
to the Faculty of the Graduate School of
The University of Texas at Austin
in Partial Fulfillment
of the Requirements
for the Degree of
Doctoral of Philosophy
The University of Texas at Austin
May, 2003
UMI Number: 3116199
________________________________________________________
UMI Microform 3116199
Copyright 2004 by ProQuest Information and Learning Company.
All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against
unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.
____________________________________________________________
ProQuest Information and Learning Company
300 North Zeeb Road
PO Box 1346
Ann Arbor, MI 48106-1346
Dedication
To my parents
Acknowledgements
I would like to express my most sincere gratitude to my committee
members: Rowland Atiase (Chair), Robert Freeman, Tom Shively, Laura Starks,
and Senyo Tse. Rowland has been an invaluable mentor to me, and has been
generous with his time and advice throughout my doctoral studies. In addition, I
wish to acknowledge with sincere thanks to many helpful suggestions of Peggy
Weber. Also, I would like to thank First Call Corporation, and Steve Sommers in
particular, for the corporate earnings guidance data. I appreciate the financial
support of Ministry of University Affairs (Thailand) and Faculty of Commerce
and Accountancy, Thammasat University (Thailand).
I would like to thank my colleagues and friends at Thammasat University
(Thailand) for their support and encouragement. Finally, my deepest thanks go to
my parents, my sister and brothers, for their unconditional love and support. They
have always been my source of strength. Without them this would have not been
possible.
v
Earnings Warnings:
Market Reaction and Management Motivation
Publication No._____________
Somchai Supattarakul, Ph.D.
The University of Texas at Austin, 2003
Supervisor: Rowland K. Atiase
This dissertation provides empirical evidence on the market reaction to
earnings warnings as well as management’s motivation to issue earnings
warnings. Specifically, this study first investigates whether self-selection bias
exists in a firm’s warning choice and if so, whether the warning effect (i.e., a
differential market reaction associated with earnings news between warning and
no-warning scenarios) is positive (negative) for good (bad) news warnings after
controlling for potential self-selection bias. I find that self-selection does exist in
a firm’s warning choice and it creates a downward bias in the warning effect. I
also find that the warning effect after controlling for self-section bias, on average,
is positive (negative) for good (bad) news warnings suggesting that empirical
evidence in Kasznik and Lev [1995] and Atiase, Supattarakul, Tse [2003] is
robust after controlling for self-selection bias. More importantly, this study
vi
investigates whether and how the warning effect affects a firm’s warning choice
(i.e., to warn or not to warn). I find that a firm’s tendency to warn is positively
associated with the warning effect after controlling for other management motives
to issue earnings warnings, i.e., litigation concerns, reputation concerns, and
information asymmetry consequence concerns, suggesting that the warning effect
itself provides management with an economic motivation to issue earnings
warnings.
vii
Table of Contents
List of Tables........................................................................................................... x
List of Figure .........................................................................................................xii
Chapter 1: Introduction .......................................................................................... 1
Chapter 2: Prior Studies and Hypotheses............................................................. 10
2.1 Differential market reaction (The warning effect) ................................ 10
2.2 Self-selection in a firm’s warning choice.............................................. 12
2.3 Management motives to issue earnings warnings ................................. 15
Chapter 3: Model Specification and Estimation Procedures................................ 20
3.1 Model specification ............................................................................... 20
3.2 Limited dependent variable or self-selectivity problem........................ 22
3.3 Lee [1978]’s approach........................................................................... 23
3.4 Methodological problems in Shu [2001]............................................... 27
Chapter 4: Sample Design and Variable Definitions ........................................... 30
4.1 Sample selection criteria ....................................................................... 30
4.2 Sample Description ............................................................................... 31
4.3 Variable Definitions .............................................................................. 32
4.3.1 Market reaction associated with earnings news (MRW and
MRN) ......................................................................................... 32
4.3.2 Determinants of market reaction associated with earnings
news (Z*) .................................................................................... 33
4.3.3 Warning choice (WARN).......................................................... 37
4.3.4 Management motives to issue earnings warnings (S*).............. 37
4.4. Sample descriptive statistics................................................................. 41
Chapter 5: Empirical Tests and Results ............................................................... 43
5.1 Self-selection and its impacts on the warning effect............................. 43
viii
5.2 A firm’s tendency to warn and the warning effect................................ 57
Chapter 6: Summary and Conclusions ................................................................. 62
6.1 Summary ............................................................................................... 62
6.2 Contributions and future research ......................................................... 63
Figure and Tables .................................................................................................. 66
References ............................................................................................................. 97
Vita….................................................................................................................. 101
ix
List of Tables
Table 1 – Reconciliation of Sample Data.............................................................. 68
Table 2 – Distribution of Earnings Warnings by Year and Quarter...................... 69
Table 3 – Sample Descriptive Statistics ................................................................ 70
Table 4 – Correlations of Market Reaction Associated with Earnings News
(MR), Unexpected Earnings (UE) and Analyst Forecast
Revisions (AFR)............................................................................... 72
Table 5 – Results of Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Warning
Choice Model to Obtain Parameters to Calculate “Inverse Mills
Ratio” ............................................................................................... 73
Table 6 – Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
Warning Scenario – Controlling for Self-selection Bias.................. 76
Table 7 – Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
No-Warning Scenario – Controlling for Self-selection Bias ........... 79
Table 8 – Distribution of the Warning Effect after Controlling for
Self-selection Bias ( RMˆ∆ ).............................................................. 82
Table 9 – Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
Warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias .... 84
Table 10 – Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
No-Warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection
Bias................................................................................................... 87
Table 11 – Distribution of the Warning Effect without Controlling for
Self-selection Bias ( RMˆ ′∆ )............................................................. 90
x
Table 12 – Distribution of Self-selection Bias (S ) in the Warning Effect ...... 92 BSˆ
Table 13 – Results of Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Warning
Choice Model ................................................................................... 94
xi
List of Figure
Figure 1 – Timeline of Events............................................................................... 67
xii
Chapter 1: Introduction
This dissertation provides empirical evidence on the market reaction to
earnings warnings and management’s motivation to issue earnings warnings.
Earnings warnings are any earnings-related management voluntary disclosures
made prior to the earnings announcement date.1 Firms use earnings warnings to
provide timely information to their shareholders and investors as well as financial
analysts regarding their expected current period performance prior to the earnings
announcement date (Ip [1997], McLean [2001] and Stone [2002]). Kasznik and
Lev [1995; hereafter KL] and Atiase, Supattarakul, and Tse [2003; hereafter AST]
find a differential market reaction to earnings news between warning and no-
warning scenarios (i.e., “the warning effect”).2 Specifically, AST document that
the warning effect is positive for good news warnings while KL and AST find that
the warning effect is negative for bad news warnings.3 Both KL and AST
document that the majority of good news firms do not warn despite a positive
warning effect, but that a significant number of bad news firms do warn despite a
negative warning effect.4 These counter-intuitive findings raise a number of
1 Consistent with prior research, I use the terms an earnings warning and earnings guidance
interchangeably for both good and bad news. Earnings warnings are also referred to as earnings
preannouncements (Soffer, Thiagarajan, and Walther [2000]).
2 Market reaction to earnings news under a warning scenario is the reaction to the news in both the
earnings warnings and earnings announcements combined while market reaction to earnings news
under a no-warning scenario is measured as the returns over a comparable window to that of a
warning scenario.
3 Good (bad) news firms are those with positive (negative) total earnings news revealed through a
warning (if any) and an earnings announcement.
4 KL document that 90% of firms with relatively large good news do not warn while 21% of firms
with relatively large bad news do warn. Similarly, AST document that 97% of all good news
firms do not warn while 13% of all bad news firms do warn. Moreover, the business press reports
1
questions: First, is the warning effect indeed positive (negative) for good (bad)
news warnings? Second, does the warning effect motivate managers to issue
earnings warnings, and if so, how? This study empirically investigates these
questions.
Healy and Palepu [2001] and Core [2001] point out that a firm’s warning
choice is likely to be endogenous. Thus, empirical evidence on the warning effect
estimated by OLS regression (as in KL and AST) may be sensitive to self-
selection bias due to biased estimates (Maddala [1991]).5 To address this
concern, I investigate (1) whether self-selection bias exists in a firm’s warning
choice, (2) whether, after controlling for self-selection bias (if any), the warning
effect is indeed positive for good news warnings, as documented in AST, and (3)
whether, after controlling for self-selection bias (if any), the warning effect
remains negative for bad news warnings, as documented in KL and AST.
KL and Shu [2001] implicitly assume that the warning effect is the
ultimate motive for management to issue earnings warnings. Prior research
suggests has documented several differential firm-characteristics between
warning and no-warning firms. I classify them into three management motives
(other than the warning effect) to warn: (1) a litigation-concern motive (i.e.,
management issue warnings to reduce or even avoid shareholder litigation risk),
(2) a reputation-concern motive (i.e., management warn to establish or maintain
good relationship or reputation with financial analysts and investors), and (3) an
that bad news warnings are more common than good news warnings (Ip [1997], Hovanesian
[2000], Stone [2002], and Wahlegren [2002]).
5 A problem of self-selection bias arises whenever there is non-random sampling caused by
individual choices (Maddala [1991]).
2
information asymmetry consequence-concern motive (i.e., management warn to
mitigate consequences of information asymmetry, such as a higher cost of
capital). Despite the implicit presumption in KL and Shu [2001] that the warning
effect motivates managers to issue earnings warnings, this motive has not been
explicitly examined in the warnings literature. This study is the first to explicitly
consider the warning effect as a motive for management to issue earnings
warnings. I examine how the warning effect affects a firm’s warning choice after
controlling for three other management motives affect a firm’s warning choice.
Specifically, this study investigates whether and how the warning effect is
associated with a firm’s tendency to warn after controlling for the effects of the
litigation-concern, reputation-concern, and information asymmetry consequence-
concern motives on a firm’s tendency to warn.
Because the warning effect is both a motive and a result of earnings
warnings, I use a simultaneous equations model with qualitative and limited
dependent variables as introduced by Lee [1978]. This approach allows me to
examine (1) the presence of self-selection bias in a firm’s warning choice, (2) the
warning effect after controlling for self-selection bias, and more importantly (3)
the relations between a firm’s tendency to warn and the warning effect after
controlling for three other management motives to warn.
Lee’s [1978] approach is briefly described as follows. First, three models
are established: (1) a warning choice model, (2) a market reaction model under a
warning scenario, and (3) a market reaction model under a no-warning scenario.
A firm’s warning choice is likely to be determined by the warning effect as well
3
as three other management motives to issue earnings warnings (i.e., litigation-
concern, reputation-concern, and information-asymmetry-concern motives).
Therefore, all four motives need to be specified as independent variables in the
warning choice model. The dependent variable for this model is the choice made
by management to warn or not to warn. The warning effect is a difference
between the market reaction when a firm warns and the market reaction when it
does not warn, ceteris paribus. However, the no-warning market reaction cannot
be observed for a firm that chooses to warn. Similarly, the warning market
reaction cannot be observed for a firm that does not warn. Lee [1978] therefore
suggests that both market reaction models be substituted directly into the warning
choice model as the warning effect. The resulting warning choice model is
estimated using Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation and the resulting
estimated coefficients are used to calculate self-selectivity variables (Inverse Mills
Ratio), which are in turn included as a dependent variable in both market reaction
models to control for potential self-selection bias. The resulting market reaction
models are estimated with Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression. OLS
regression should yield unbiased estimators once self-selection bias is controlled
for, allowing empirical assessment of the warning effect.6 Finally, the original
warning choice model is estimated with the unbiased warning effect using Probit
Maximum Likelihood Estimation and thus associations between a firm’s tendency
6 Conceptually, this approach allows me to estimate the “what would have been” market reaction.
For example, for a warning firm, I am able to estimate what its market reaction would have been if
it had not warned. Similarly, for a no-warning firm, I am able to estimate what its market reaction
would have been if it had warned.
4
to warn and the warning effect after controlling for three other management
motives are investigated.
My sample consists of all firms included in the Institutional Broker
Estimate System (I/B/E/S) database from 1998 to 2000. I obtain reported
quarterly earnings and financial analysts’ quarterly earnings estimates from
I/B/E/S. Earnings warnings are obtained from the First Call Historical database.
Quarterly earnings announcement dates and selected quarterly accounting
information are obtained from the Compustat database while daily security returns
are obtained from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) daily stock
database. Security Data Company (SDC) is the source for debt and equity
issuance data. My final sample consists of 23,018 firm-quarters (4,482 firms) of
which, 13,818 firm-quarters are good news and 9,200 are bad news.7 Consistent
with prior research, I find that firms are more apt to warn about bad news than
good news. Specifically, 1,258 (9.10%) firm-quarters with good news have
earnings warnings while 2,045 (22.23%) firm-quarters with bad news have
earnings warnings.
As expected, I find evidence of self-selection bias in a firm’s warning
choice. Moreover, after controlling for the bias, I find that the warning effect, on
average, is positive for good news warnings and negative for bad news warnings.
This suggests that even though self-selection bias exists in a firm’s warning
choice, the empirical findings in KL and AST do not appear to be materially
7 Types of news (i.e., good news and bad news) are classified by total earnings news (UE or a
price-deflated analyst forecast error) revealed through the warning (if any) and the earnings
announcement. See a definition of UE in chapter 4.
5
altered by it. I also find that self-selection in a firm’s warning choice appears to
create a downward bias in the warning effect.
More importantly, I find that a firm’s tendency to warn is significantly
positively associated with the warning effect after controlling for three other
management motives, suggesting that the warning effect itself provides
management with an economic incentive to issue earnings warnings. For other
management motives, I document that, consistent with prior research, the
litigation-concern motive and the reputation-concern motives determine a firm’s
warning choice. That is, my empirical evidence suggests that firms that are more
vulnerable to shareholder litigation are more likely to warn than other firms and
that firms that are more concerned with their reputation with financial analysts
and investors are more likely to warn than other firms. The association between a
firm’s tendency to warn and the information asymmetry consequence-concern
motives, however, is insignificant.
In summary, my findings suggest that although the warning effect
provides management with an economic motivation to issue earnings warnings, it
is only one of several management motives. Therefore, the notion that a firm will
warn only if the warning effect is positive and will not warn otherwise, as implied
by KL and Shu [2001], is not completely accurate. A more appropriate depiction
is that that a firm prefers a more positive warning effect, all else being equal.
My findings contribute to the literature on management earnings warnings
in two ways. First, I provide empirical evidence suggesting that self-selection
does exist in a firm’s warning choice and it creates a downward bias in the
6
warning effect and that after controlling for the bias, the warning effect, on
average, remains positive (negative) for good (bad) news warnings. Thus,
contrary to Shu [2001] findings, I find that the results in KL and AST are not
altered by the self-selection bias. Shu [2001] re-examines KL’s results on bad
news warnings of firms with bad news of at least 1% of a stock price and finds
that the warning effect is positive. Her results, however, could be spurious due to
logical inconsistency resulting in model misspecification, and methodological
problems avoided in my design.8 Furthermore, Shu [2001] only examines the
warning effect for bad news warnings of firms with relatively large bad news
while I examine the warning effect for both good news and bad news warnings of
firms with all magnitudes of news.
Second, the main contribution of this study is that it is the first to
investigate an association between a firm’s tendency to warn and the warning
effect. Prior research has not specified a warning choice model with the warning
effect as a determinant of the warning choice. Overall, my findings suggest that
the stock market responds to earnings warnings and that managers consider a
capital-market incentive (i.e., the warning effect) when they are making a warning
decision, among other things.
8 Shu [2001] implicitly assumes that the warning effect is the sole determinant of a firm’s warning
choice. She models her warning choice model without the warning effect as an independent
variable, instead includes certain firm-specific characteristics, which prior research has found to be
other determinants of a firm’s warning choice. This logical inconsistency clearly results in the
model misspecification. Furthermore, Maddala [1983; 1991], among others, explicitly suggests
that (1) self-selectivity variables should be used to estimate unbiased OLS estimates, and never be
used to estimate dependent variables; and (2) the warning effect should be estimated based on
estimated values of both market reaction associated with earnings news under warning and no-
warning scenarios. Shu [2001] fails to follow these guidelines.
7
Potential avenues for future research may include an investigation of
management motives to issue different types of earnings warnings, namely, point,
range, open-ended, and qualitative warnings as well as a use of self-selection
analysis in other settings. Specifically, an investigation of whether and how the
warning effect determines a firm’s choice of warning type would give insights
regarding management voluntary disclosure choice. In addition, management
may self-selectively choose one accounting choice over others and management’s
decision may affect how the stock market reacts to his accounting choice
decision.
The remainder of this dissertation is organized as follows. Chapter 2
discusses prior studies on the warning effect, self-selection bias in a firm’s
warning choice, and management motives to issue earnings warnings. Chapter 2
also develops hypotheses regarding the existence of self-selection bias in a firm’s
warning choice and the association between a firm’s tendency to warn and the
warning effect. Chapter 3 specifies the market reaction and warning choice
models, and describes estimation procedures that address self-selection bias.
Chapter 4 addresses the sample selection criteria, defines all empirical proxies
employed in the study and discusses the basic characteristics of the sample firms.
Chapter 5 presents empirical tests and discusses the results of these tests related to
the presence of self-selection bias in a firm’s warning choice and its impacts on
the warning effect as well as an association between a firm’s tendency to warn
and the warning effect after controlling for three other management motives to
8
issue earnings warnings. Chapter 6 reviews the contribution of the study,
proposes possible avenues for future research and concludes the dissertation.
9
Chapter 2: Prior Studies and Hypotheses
This chapter discusses prior studies on differential market reactions
induced by earnings warnings (i.e., the warning effect), management motives for
issuing earnings warnings and issues related to self-selection bias. It also
develops hypotheses regarding the existence of the self-selection bias in a firm’s
warning choice and the association between a firm’s tendency to warn and the
warning effect.
2.1 DIFFERENTIAL MARKET REACTION (THE WARNING EFFECT)
Kasznik and Lev [1995; hereafter KL] examine whether there is a
differential market reaction associated with earnings news between firms that
warn and firms that do not warn (i.e., a differential market reaction induced by
earnings warnings or “the warning effect”). Market reaction to earnings news for
warning firms is the reaction to the news in both the earnings warnings and the
earnings announcements (i.e., a combination of cumulative abnormal returns
around the warning date and the earnings announcement date). Market reaction to
earnings news for no-warning firms is measured as the cumulative abnormal
returns over a comparable window to that of warning firms. Their sample is
limited to firms with large earnings news (i.e., the absolute value of earnings news
of at least 1% of the beginning-of-quarter stock price) from 1988 to 1990. They
find that, all else being equal, market reaction associated with earnings news of
bad news firms that warn is more negative than that of bad news firms that do not
10
warn (i.e., a negative warning effect for bad news warnings). KL specifically
state that “We consider this finding [a negative warning effect] counter-intuitive
because a warning generally provides partial information about the subsequent
earnings surprise, and is therefore expected to be rewarded by investors” (pp. 128,
KL). However, they find insignificant results for good news firms.
Atiase, Supattarakul, and Tse [2003, hereafter AST] extend KL by
examining the warning effect for firms with earnings news covering a broad range
of magnitude over the period 1995 to 1999. They find the market reaction
associated with earnings news of good news firms that warn is more positive than
that of good news firms that do not warn (i.e., a positive warning effect for good
news warnings).9 In addition, consistent with empirical results in KL, they find
the market reaction associated with earnings news of bad news firms that warn is
more negative than that of bad news firms that do not warn (i.e., a negative
warning effect for bad news warnings).
Libby and Tan [1999] provide a possible explanation for a negative
warning effect for bad news warnings. They conjecture that a negative warning
effect for bad news warnings arises from financial analysts’ (or investors’)
sequential information processing. Their experimental evidence suggests that a
bad news warning itself does not give rise to a negative warning effect, but rather
financial analysts’ sequential information processing induces the negative
warning effect. Specifically, they find that financial analysts’ forecasts of future
9 This seems to be consistent with King, Pownell, and Waymire’s [1990] conjecture that
management voluntary disclosures reduce investors’ need to privately acquire information, thus
reducing capital-market transaction costs (i.e., the transaction cost saving argument). This
transaction cost savings may induce investors’ positive response to earnings warnings.
11
earnings are lower when they receive a bad news warning first and then later
receive an earning announcement than when they receive no warnings
whatsoever. In addition, they find that financial analysts’ forecasts of future
earnings are higher when they receive a bad news warning concurrently with an
earnings announcement than when they receive no warnings whatsoever. This
suggests that the bad news warning itself has a positive warning effect, but the
fact that financial analysts have to revise their forecasts twice (i.e., once after
receiving a bad news warning and again after receiving an earnings
announcement) induces a negative warning effect. Experimental results in Libby
and Tan [1999] corroborate empirical results in KL and AST that the warning
effect is negative for bad news warnings.
2.2 SELF-SELECTION IN A FIRM’S WARNING CHOICE
Healy and Palepu [2001] and Core [2001] point out in their review papers
that a firm’s warning choice is likely to be endogenous.10 Specifically, a firm
chooses to warn or not to warn based on certain exogenous factors, which are
likely to represent management motives to issue earnings warnings, and thus
characteristics of warning firms and no-warning firms are likely to be
systematically different (e.g., Cox [1985], Waymire [1985], KL, Shu [2001],
Chen [2002], and AST). As a consequence, the warning effect estimated by OLS
regression (as in KL and AST) may be sensitive to potential self-selection bias
due to biased estimators (Maddala [1983; 1991]). Market reaction associated with
10 A firm does not randomly choose to warn or not to warn or a firm self-selectively chooses to
warn or not to warn.
12
earnings news is observable only in the state chosen by the firm (warning or no-
warning) while market reaction associated with earnings news in the alternative
condition (no-warning or warning) is unobservable. For example, if firm A
decides to warn, the market reaction associated with its earnings ne._.ws in a
warning scenario is observable, but the market reaction associated with its
earnings news in a no-warning scenario is unobservable. This creates a limited
dependent variable or self-selectivity problem. In the presence of a limited
dependent variable or self-selectivity problem, OLS regression cannot be used to
obtain unbiased estimated coefficients (Maddala [1983; 1991]).
This study examines how earnings warnings affect the market reaction
associated with earnings news, after controlling for potential self-selection bias. I
investigate (1) whether self-selection bias exists in a firm’s warning choice, (2)
whether, after controlling for potential self-selection bias, the warning effect
remains positive for good news warnings, as documented in AST, and (3)
whether, after controlling for potential self-selection bias, the warning effect
remains negative for bad news warnings, as found in KL and AST.
Shu [2001] re-examines KL’s results by using Heckman two-stage
regression to control for potential self-selection bias in an attempt to explain KL’s
counter-intuitive findings that the warning effect is negative for bad news
warnings of firms with relatively large bad news. She finds that after controlling
for the self-selection bias, the warning effect is positive for warning firms, but the
warning effect would have been negative for no-warning firms had they decided
to warn. She concludes that the firms in her sample, on average, make rational
13
warning choices. Her findings, however, could be spurious due to a problem of
logical inconsistency resulting in model misspecification, and some
methodological problems as briefly discussed below.
Shu’s conclusion rests on the unstated premise that a firm will warn only
if the warning effect is positive and will not warn otherwise, i.e., the warning
effect is the sole management motive to issue earnings warnings. However, the
warning choice model she employs fails to include the warning effect as an
independent variable; instead she includes certain firm-specific characteristics that
proxy for management motives to issue earnings warnings. As a result, her model
is misspecified.
Furthermore, according to Maddala [1983; 1991], among others, self-
selectivity variables should only be used to obtain unbiased OLS estimates (in the
market reaction models), and never be used to estimate dependent variables (i.e.,
market reactions associated with earnings news); and differential market reactions
in this case, i.e., the warning effect, should be calculated based on estimated
market reactions associated with earnings news under warning and no-warning
scenarios. Shu [2001] fails to follow these guidelines.
I use a simultaneous equations model with qualitative and limited
dependent variables as introduced by Lee [1978] to more properly address the
self-selection issue. Lee’s [1978] approach avoids the logical inconsistency and
methodological problems found in Shu [2001]. Chapter 3 describes this approach
in detail.
14
As discussed earlier, prior research has documented that firm
characteristics of warning and no-warning firms are systematically different and
thus it is likely that the firm characteristics are related to the firm’s decision to
warn or not to warn. As a result, I hypothesize that self-selection bias exists in a
firm’s warning choice. However, it is not clear whether or not extant empirical
findings that the warning effect is positive for good news warnings (AST) and
negative for bad news warnings (KL and AST) are influenced by the potential
self-selection bias. Therefore, I do not make any predictions regarding the
sensitivity of the empirical results in KL and AST to the possible self-selection
bias.
2.3 MANAGEMENT MOTIVES TO ISSUE EARNINGS WARNINGS
Prior research has documented seven differential firm-characteristics
between warnings and no-warning firms: (1) membership in high-litigation risk
industries, (2) the magnitude of earnings news, (3) market capitalization, (4) past
warning pattern, (5) analyst following, (6) membership in regulated industries,
and (7) future external finance offering. I classify these firm-characteristics into
three management motives to issue earnings warnings: (1) a litigation-concern
motive (items 1-3), (2) a reputation-concern motive (items 4-6), and (3) an
information asymmetry consequence-concern motive (item 7). Therefore, these
three motives need to be controlled for in the warning choice model.
15
Skinner [1994] suggests that management may issue earnings warnings to
reduce or even avoid shareholder litigation risk.11 Skinner [1997] provides
empirical evidence suggesting that earnings warnings can reduce settlement
amounts in shareholder lawsuits consistent with the litigation-concern motive.
Baginski, Hassell, and Kimbrough [2002] also find that a firm’s
shareholder litigation environment has a significant impact on a firm’s warning
decision to warn or not to warn. Similarly, KL and Shu [2001] provide empirical
evidence suggesting that firms in industries that tend to be vulnerable to
shareholder litigation (mostly high-tech industries) are more likely to warn than
firms in other industries. In addition, they find that firms with relatively large
earnings news, especially bad news, and those with large market capitalization,
who are likely to be targets of shareholder lawsuits, are more likely to warn than
other firms. All these studies support the litigation-concern motive.
Skinner [1994] also conjectures that management may issue earnings
warnings to establish or maintain a good reputation with financial analysts and
investors. Miller and Piotroski [2000] and Chen [2002] provide empirical
evidence, consistent with this reputation-concern motive. Specifically, Miller and
Piotroski [2000] find that firms that have issued earnings warnings in prior
periods are likely to do so in the current period, suggesting that these firms intend
to establish or maintain a reputation as warning firms.
11 Vicker [1999] states in her article in Business Week that if companies fail to meet analysts’
estimates (i.e., have bad news on the earnings announcement date), they risk shareholder lawsuits.
In fact, she reports that shareholders recently filed suit against Compaq Company Corp. charging
that the company did not timely inform them about its disappointing performance.
16
Chen [2002] finds that analyst following is positively associated with a
firm’s tendency to warn. Firms with a large analyst following need to maintain a
good reputation with their analysts. Issuing earnings warnings is one way to
maintain a good relationship with financial analysts.12
In addition, KL find that firms in regulated industries (i.e., utility,
communication, and financial firms) are less likely to warn than other firms. KL
speculate that this may be because firms in the regulated industries are required to
disclose financial information in more detail and thus the incremental benefit of
earnings warnings to financial analysts and investors is likely to be minimal,
compared to the benefit for firms in unregulated industries.
Lang and Lundholm [1993] conjecture that high quality disclosures may
reduce information asymmetry and increase firm value at the time of debt or
equity issuance. Botosan [1997] documents that disclosure quality is adversely
associated with cost of equity capital and similarly, Sengupta [1998] finds an
adverse relationship between disclosure quality and cost of debt. Ruland, Tung,
and George [1990], Frankel, McNichols, and Wilson [1995] and Miller and
Piotroski [2000] provide empirical results that firms planning to issue public
offerings (either debt or equity) are more likely to provide voluntary disclosures
to the stock market. Shu [2001] also finds a positive association between a firm’s
tendency to warn and a firm’s tendency to issue debt or equity in the market.
Taken as a whole, these studies indicate that earnings warnings may be a
mechanism used to reduce potential consequences of information asymmetry
12 Skinner [1994] argues that financial analysts may impose costs on firms whose managers are
less than candid about a potential earnings surprise. For example, analysts may choose not to
follow firms that continue not to warn analysts about their earnings surprise.
17
(e.g., a high cost of capital). This conforms to the information asymmetry
consequence-concern motive to issue earnings warnings.
KL and Shu [2001] tacitly imply that the warning effect is management’s
sole motive to issue earnings warnings, i.e., a firm will warn only if the warning
effect is positive and will not otherwise. For example, KL specifically state that
their finding that the warning effect is negative for bad news warnings is
“counter-intuitive.” Shu [2001] likewise concludes that bad news firms in her
sample, on average, make rational warning choices based on her problematic
findings that the warning effect is positive for warning firms but the warning
effect would have been negative for no-warning firms if they had decided to warn.
It is unlikely that the warning effect is the sole management motive to
issue earnings warnings since prior research shows litigation concerns, reputation
concerns, and information asymmetry consequence concerns all appear to
motivate management to issue earnings warnings. Despite the implicit
presumption in KL and Shu [2001] that the warning effect motivates managers to
issue earnings warnings, this motive has not been explicitly examined in the
warnings literature. This study is the first to explicitly consider the warning effect
itself as a management motive for issuing earnings warnings and examine how the
warning effect affect a firm’s warning choice. How the warning effect affects a
firm’s warning decision (to warn or not to warn) is a fundamental question that
has not been addressed in the earnings warnings literature. This study therefore
investigates whether and how the warning effect affects a firm’s tendency to warn
after controlling for litigation concerns, reputation concerns, and information
18
asymmetry consequence concerns. Since intuitively management prefers a more
positive market reaction, all else being equal, I hypothesize that a firm’s
propensity to warn is positively associated with the warning effect.
Because the warning effect is both a motive and a result of earnings
warnings, I use a simultaneous equations model with qualitative and limited
dependent variables introduced by Lee [1978]. This approach allows me to
measure the warning effect after controlling for self-selection bias and to
explicitly examine the associations between a firm’s tendency to warn and the
warning effect after controlling for three other management motives.
19
Chapter 3: Model Specification and Estimation Procedures
This chapter describes the models and estimation procedures used in the
study. I specify market reaction models for warning and no-warning scenarios
and a warning choice model. I also employ estimation procedures to deal with
possible self-selection bias. This study implements a simultaneous equations
model with qualitative and limited dependent variables as introduced by Lee
[1978]. Lee’s [1978] approach allows me to estimate the unbiased warning effect
as well as to explicitly examine the association between a firm’s tendency to warn
and the warning effect, controlling for other management motives to issue
earnings warnings.
3.1 MODEL SPECIFICATION
The two separate market reaction models under warning and no-warning
scenarios and the warning choice model appear as follows:
Market reaction model under a warning scenario:
)σN(0,~ε where;εZββMRW 2W
W
i
W
i
*
i
*W
1
*W
0i ++= (1)
Market reaction model under a no-warning scenario:
)σN(0,~ε where;εZββMRN 2N
N
i
N
i
*
i
*N
1
*N
0i ++= (2)
Warning choice model:
i
*
i
*
2i
*
1
*
0i εSδMRδδ WARN ++∆+= ; (3)
≤
>=
0 WARNif 0
0 WARNif 1
WARNwhere *
i
*
i
i
In Eqs. (1) and (2), MRWi and MRNi denote firm i’s market reactions
associated with earnings news under warning and no-warning scenarios,
20
respectively, and denotes a vector of firm i’s firm-specific characteristics that
determine firm i’s market reaction to earnings news. denote firm i’s
random residuals under warning and no-warning scenarios and are assumed to be
and , respectively.
*
iZ
σN(0,
N
i
W
i ε andε
)σN(0, 2W )
2
N
In Eq. (3), iii MRNMRW∆MR −= , is firm i’s warning effect (i.e., the
differential market reaction to earnings news between warning and no-warning
scenarios) and S represents a vector of firm i’s firm-specific characteristics that
proxy for other management motives to issue earnings warnings: the litigation-
concern motive, the reputation-concern motive, and the information asymmetry
consequence-concern motive.
*
i
*
iWARN
WARN
is a latent variable that represents firm i’s unobserved tendency
to warn; denotes firm i’s observable warning choice, where i 1WARNi =
if firm i chooses to warn and 0WARNi = if firm i chooses not to warn. The
models assume that 1iWARN = if and if
. This study is the first to specify a warning choice model using the
warning effect as one of determinants of warning choice.
0WARN*i > 0WARNi =
0*i ≤WARN
Since vectors in Eqs. (1) and (2) and S in Eq. (3) contain common
variables, let and S , where X
*
iZ
Zi
*
i
]X[Z i
*
i = ]SX[ ii*i = i denotes a vector of
variables common to the warning choice and market reaction models for firm i.
Thus, Eqs. (1), (2), and (3), respectively, are re-written as follows:
W
ii
W
2i
W
1
W
0i εXβZββMRW +++= (4)
N
ii
N
2i
N
1
N
0i εXβZββMRN +++= (5)
ii3i2ii10i εSδXδ)MRN(MRWδδ WARN +++−+= (6)
21
3.2 LIMITED DEPENDENT VARIABLE OR SELF-SELECTIVITY PROBLEM
If, for any particular firm i, both MRWi and MRNi were observable, firm
i’s warning effect ( ) could be easily measured as , and the
warning choice model (Eq. (6)) could be estimated using Probit Maximum
Likelihood Estimation. For any particular firm i, either MRW
i∆MR
N
1
N β and
ii MRNMRW −
iW iNRˆM
i or MRNi is
observable depending upon firm i’s warning choice (WARNi), but not both. For
example, if firm i decides to warn (WARNi = 1), MRWi is observable, but MRNi
is not. Similarly, if firm i decides not to warn (WARNi = 0), MRNi is observable,
but MRWi is not. Even if only one state is observable, if the waning choice is
random, OLS regression gives unbiased estimates coefficients
( ) for Eqs. (4) and (5); and are then
easily obtained. As a result, is measurable and the warning choice model
(Eq. (6)) can again be estimated using Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation.
1
N
0
W
2
W
1
W
0 β ,β,β,β,β RˆM
iRMˆ∆
It follows from the warning choice model (Eq. (6)) that firm i self-
selectively chooses to warn or not to warn. That is, firm i chooses to warn or not
to warn based on the warning effect ( ) and other management motives to
issue earnings warnings ( ). This creates a limited dependent variable or
self-selectivity problem. In this situation, the error terms, , in Eqs. (4)
and (5) are conditioned on firm i’s warning choice (WARN
i∆MR
ii S and X
N
i
W
i ε and ε
i). In this setting, Eqs.
(4) and (5) are re-written as follows:
;1)WARN(εXβZββMRW i
W
ii
W
2i
W
1
W
0i =+++= (7)
0 1)WARNE(ε where i
W
i ≠=
22
;0)WARN(εXβZββMRN i
N
ii
N
2i
N
1
N
0i =+++= (8)
0 0)WARNE(ε where i
N
i ≠=
Since 01)WARNE(ε i
W
i ≠= and 00)WARNE(ε iNi ≠=
)σN(0,~ε 2W
W
i
, the OLS
regression assumption that and is clearly violated.
As a result, using OLS regression to estimate Eqs. (4) and (5) gives biased
estimated coefficients and the warning effect estimated based on these biased
coefficients is biased as well.
)σN(0,~ε 2W
W
i
If 1)WARNE(ε i
W
i = and 0)WARNε iNi =E( can be estimated and
incorporated into Eqs. (7) and (8), the conditional error terms will have a mean of
zero, yielding unbiased OLS estimates.
3.3 LEE [1978]’S APPROACH
Generally, to correct for self-selectivity (i.e., to obtain 1)WARNE(ε i
W
i =
and 0)WARNE(ε i
N
i = in Eqs. (7) and (8)), Heckman two-stage regression (as
described in Maddala [1983; 1991]) is used.13 If the warning choice is modeled
without the warning effect (∆MR), the warning choice model can be estimated
using Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation. Next, the self-selectivity variables
for warning and no-warning firms are calculated based on estimated coefficients
from the warning choice model. The self-selectivity variables are then
incorporated into the corresponding market reaction models to control for
potential self-selection bias and OLS regression is used to estimate the resulting
market reaction models, yielding unbiased estimated coefficients. Finally,
13 Shu [2001] uses Heckman two-stage regression.
23
unbiased and are obtained and an unbiased estimate of is
measured as .
iWRˆM
RˆM
iNRˆM
iNRˆM−
M
iRMˆ∆
iW
R
MRN
i
0δ=
(+
W
1β
-MRW
∆MR
iWARN
W
0 ,β
W
01(βδ+
W
21(βδ −
N
0
W
2 β ,β ,
The warning choice model (Eq. (6)) in this study is specified with the
warning effect (∆ ) and other management motives (S ). Since
, Eqs. (7) and (8) need to be estimated before estimating
Eq. (6). Equations (7) and (8), however, cannot be estimated properly without Eq.
(6) due to the self-selectivity problem. Therefore, Heckman two-stage regression
is not appropriate. Lee [1978] introduces a simultaneous equations model with
qualitative and limited dependent variables that can be used in this situation.
*
i
∆MR =
Lee’s [1978] procedures require using Eqs. (4) and (5) to substitute MRWi
and MRNi as in Eq. (6), resulting in the following equation.
i
N
1
W
11
N
i
W
i1
N
0 )Zβ(βδ)ε(εδ)β −+−+−
ii3i2
N
2 εSδ)Xδ)β +++ (9)
Since are not identified in Eq. (9), this model
cannot be used to obtain estimates of these coefficients. Letting
, , ,
and , Eq. (9) may be re-written as
N
2
N
1 β and ,β ,
)ε(εδ)ββ NW1
N
0
W
0 −+− γ1(δδγ 100 +=
33 δγ =
)β(βδ N1
W
11 −= 3N2W212 δ)β(βδγ +−=
ii3i2i10i εSγXγZγγWARN ++++= (10)
3210 γand , γ, γ,γ are identified in Eq. (10) and can be estimated using
Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation.
Assume that in Eqs. (4), (5), and (10), respectively, are
trivariate normally distributed, with mean vector zero and covariance matrix
i
N
i
W
i ε and ,ε ,ε
Σ ,
where
24
==
1
σσ
σσσ
Σε),ε,cov(ε Nε
2
N
WεWN
2
W
NW (11)
Note that var is assumed since the ( ) 1ε i = γ ’s in Eq. (10) are estimable
only up to a scale factor (Maddala [1983])14. Note also that the conditional
distribution of , given , is normal, with mean and variance
and the conditional distribution of ε , is normal, with mean and
variance (Maddala [1983]). Consistent with the Heckman two-stage
approach,
W
iε
2
Nσ
iε
ε
iWεεσ
2
Wε
2
W σσ −
iNεεσi
N
i εgiven ,
2
Nσ −
1)WARNi =E(εWi and 0)WARNE(εNi i = can be measured as
follows:
1)WARNE(ε i
W
i = )SγXγZγγ ε E(ε i3i2i10iWi +++≤=
)iSγXγZγγε εE(σ 3i2i10iiWε +++≤=
)SiγXγZγγε E(ε σ 3i2i10iiWε +++≤=
+++
+++=
)SγXγZγΦ(γ
)SγXγZγφ(γ-
σ
i3i2i10
i3i2i10
Wε (12)
0)WARNE(ε i
N
i = )SγXγZγγ ε E(ε i3i2i10iNi +++≥=
)iSγXγZγγ ε εE(σ 3i2i10iiNε +++≥=
)SiγXγZγγ ε E(ε σ 3i2i10iiNε +++≥=
+++
+++=
)SγXγZγΦ(γ-1
)SγXγZγφ(γσ
i3i2i10
i3i2i10
Nε (13)
where and are the standard normal density function and cumulative
distribution function, respectively.
φ(.) Φ(.)
14 The probit method gives a scale estimate, σγ , where σ 2 ( )iεvar= .
25
As noted earlier, can be estimated from Eq. (10). Letting
, , and . Thus, the market
reaction model under a warning scenario (Eq. (7)) is re-written as
3210 γˆ and ,γˆ ,γˆ ,γˆ
i3Sγˆ Wε
W σπ =i2i10i XγˆZγˆγˆψ +++= NεN σ π =
e
)Φ(ψ
)φ(ψπXβZββMRW Wi
i
iW
i
W
2i
W
1
W
0i +
−+++= (14)
0 1)WARNE(e where i
W
i == . The market reaction model under a no-warning
scenario is similarly re-written as
e
)Φ(ψ-1
)φ(ψπXβZββMRN Ni
i
iN
i
N
2i
N
1
N
0i +
+++= (15)
0 0)WARNE(e where i
N
i ==
N
2
N
1
N
0 βˆ and ,βˆ ,βˆ
. Thus, Eqs. (14) and (15) are now estimated using
OLS regression to obtain the unbiased OLS estimated coefficients, β
.
,βˆ ,βˆ ,ˆ W2
W
1
W
0
From Eqs. (7), (8), (14) and (15), it follows that
−==
)Φ(ψ
)φ(ψ
π)1WARNE(ε
i
iW
i
W
i and
−== )Φ(ψ1
)φ(ψπ)0WARNε
i
iN
i
N
i
Wπ Nπ
Wπ Nπ
E( .
The self-selection bias exists in a firm’s warning choice if and are non-
zero since the expected values of are then non-zero.15 As I hypothesize
that the self-selection bias exists in a firm’s warning choice, I expect and
to be significantly different from zero.
N
i
W
i ε andε
After obtaining unbiased β from Eqs. (14) and
(15), the warning effect (∆ ) is estimated as follows:
N
2
N
1
N
0
W
2
W
1
W
0 βˆ and ,βˆ ,βˆ ,βˆ ,βˆ ,ˆ
MR
15 Specifically, non-zero and imply that OLS estimated coefficients in Eqs. (7) and (8)
are biased due to omitted variables – self-selectivity variables (i.e., additional terms in squared
blankets in Eqs. (14) and (15)). These self-selectivity variables are generally referred to as the
“Inverse Mills Ratio.”
Wπ Nπ
26
iRMˆ∆ ii NRˆM WRˆM −=
βˆZβˆβˆ i
W
1
W
0 ++=
W
1
N
0
W
0 βˆ()βˆβˆ( +−=
)XβˆZβˆβˆ(X i
N
2i
N
1
N
0i
W
2 ++−
i
N
2
W
2i
N
1 )Xβˆβˆ()Zβˆ −+− (16)
It is now possible to proceed to determine whether the warning effect
( RMˆ∆ ) is positive (negative) for good (bad) news warnings after controlling for
the self-selection bias.16
In order to investigate whether and how the warning effect affects a firm’s
tendency to warn after controlling for other possible management motives, I
estimate Eq. (6), the warning choice model, using Probit Maximum Likelihood
Estimation as follows:
ii3i2i10i εSδXδRMˆδδWARN +++∆+= (17)
Since I expect a firm’s tendency to warn to be positively associated with
the warning effect, I predict to be significantly positive.17 1δˆ
3.4 METHODOLOGICAL PROBLEMS IN SHU [2001]
Both in Eq. (16) are calculated without self-selectivity
variables. According to Maddala [1983; 1991], self-selectivity variables should
only be used to estimate unbiased OLS estimated coefficients of independent
variables (i.e., and β ) and should not be used to estimate dependent variables
ii NRˆM and WRˆM
Wβˆ Nˆ
17 δ1 estimated from eq. (17) may be biased (or underestimated) since ∆MR is the estimated value,
not the observed one.
16 For a warning firm, M is the “what would have been” market reaction if it had not warned.
Similarly, for a no-warning firm, is the “what would have been” market reaction if it had
warned.
NRˆ
WRˆM
27
(i.e., ). Moreover, ∆ is calculated based on both estimated
and (Lee [1978] and Maddala [1983; 1991]). Observed MRW
ii NRˆM and WRˆM
iW iNRˆM
W
N
ii NRˆMMRWR −=
ii WRˆMRMˆ∆ −=
iRMˆ
RˆM
RˆM
RˆM
Mˆ∆
i
and MRNi should not be used to calculate ∆ . iRMˆ
RˆM
Shu [2001], in attempting to control for the self-selection bias, violates
both of these guidelines. Shu [2001] estimates M for warning firms and
for no-warning firms by including the self-selectivity variables along with
other independent variables but fails to estimates for warning firms and
for no-warning firms. As a result, she calculates the warning effect for
warning firms with observed MRW and estimated M (i.e.,
if firm i warns), and calculates the warning effect for
no-warning firms with estimated and observed MRN
(i.e., if firm i does not warn). Therefore, her results
could be spurious due to these methodological mistakes.
NRˆ
WRˆM
W
NRˆ
i
iMRN
More importantly, her model is misspecified, reflecting a logical
inconsistency. Specifically, she assumes that a firm will warn only if the warning
effect is positive which is equivalent to assuming that the warning effect is the
sole motive underlying the warning decision. However, she specifies her warning
choice model without including the warning effect as an independent variable,
instead including certain firm-specific characteristics (i.e., tentative proxies for
management motives other than the warning effect).
In summary, Shu’s [2001] empirical findings that, on average, the warning
effect is positive for warning firms and it would have been negative for no-
warning firms had they warned, could be spurious due to the methodological
28
problems and the logical inconsistency that compromises her model specification.
Her conclusion that bad news firms in her sample make rational warning
decisions may be unfounded.
29
Chapter 4: Sample Design and Variable Definitions
4.1 SAMPLE SELECTION CRITERIA
Firms must meet the following selection criteria to be included in the
sample. The sample firm must have (1) quarterly earnings announcements during
the period 1998-2000 available on the Institutional Broker Estimate System
(I/B/E/S) database; (2) the corresponding quarterly earnings announcement date
(quarters t), and the prior quarter’s earnings announcement date (quarters t-1) as
well as price per share, book value per share, and number of shares outstanding at
the beginning of quarter t available on the Quarterly Compustat database; (3) at
least one individual analyst forecast of quarters t’s and t+1’s EPS made between
the announcement of quarter t-1’s earnings and (i) the 30th day following the
announcement of quarter t-1’s earnings or (ii) quarter t’s fiscal quarter end,
whichever comes first, plus at least one individual analyst forecast of quarter
t+1’s EPS made within 30 days following the announcement of quarter t’s
earnings available on the I/B/E/S database (See a timeline in figure 1); and (4)
daily security returns for the period extending from 98 days preceding quarter t-
1’s earnings announcement date to one day after quarter t’s earnings
announcement date available on the Center for Research in Security Prices
(CRSP) Daily Stock database.
Criteria (1) - (3) are required to compute unexpected earnings, analyst
forecast revisions, market values and book-to-market ratios. Criterion (4) is
required to calculate cumulative abnormal returns, betas, and return variations. In
30
addition, data on debt and equity issuances are obtained from the Security Data
Company (SDC) database.
Earnings warnings include any earnings-related voluntary disclosures
made by management in either quantitative or qualitative form available in the
First Call Historical database. The warnings included in the sample must have
been released during the warning period, which is defined as the period between
(i) the 31st day after quarter t-1’s earnings announcement date, or (ii) quarter t’s
fiscal quarter end, whichever comes first, and quarter t’s earnings announcement
date (See a timeline in figure 1).
4.2 SAMPLE DESCRIPTION
Table 1 provides a reconciliation of sample data and reports the sequential
filters applied to obtain the final sample: 91,561 firm-quarters (10,840 firms)
meet criterion (1). Criterion (2) eliminates 32,520 firm-quarters. I remove 34,612
firm-quarters that do not meet criterion (3). 412 firm-quarters fail to meet
criterion (4) resulting in a sample of 24,017 firm-quarters (4,564 firms) that meet
all four criteria. Of these, 999 firm-quarters with extreme values (i.e., the highest
and lowest 1%) of cumulative abnormal returns, unexpected earnings, and/or
analyst forecast revisions are eliminated leaving a final sample of 23,018 firm-
quarters (4,482 firms), consisting of 13,818 (60.03%) firm-quarters with good
news and 9,200 (39.97%) firm-quarters with bad news.18 Of the 13,818 good
18 Good (bad) news firms are those with positive (negative) total earnings news revealed through a
warning (if any) and an earnings announcement. Total earnings news is UE defined in section
4.3.2.
31
news firm-quarters, there are 1,258 (9.10%) earnings warnings and of the 9,200
bad news firm-quarters, there are 2,045 (22.23%) earnings warnings. This
distribution is consistent with empirical findings in Skinner (1994), Baginski,
Hassell, and Waymire (1994), KL, and AST that bad news firms are more likely
to warn than good news firms.
Table 2 reports the distribution of earnings warnings in the final sample by
year and quarter. There are 1,078 (14.76%) firm-quarters of earnings warnings in
1998, 1,019 (13.09%) in 1999 and 1,206 (15.21%) in 2000. In each of the three
years, bad news firms issue more earnings warnings than good news firms: In
1998, there are 363 (9.11%) good news warnings and 715 (21.54%) bad news
warnings, in 1999 there are 427 (8.82%) good news warnings and 592 (20.09%)
bad news warnings and in 2000 there are 468 (9.37%) good news warnings and
738 (25.15%) bad news warnings.
4.3 VARIABLE DEFINITIONS
4.3.1 Market reaction associated with earnings news (MRW and MRN)
The market reaction associated with earnings news under a warning
scenario of firm i in quarter t, denoted MRWit, and the market reaction associated
with earnings news under a no-warning scenario of firm i in quarter t, denoted
MRNit, are defined as the cumulative abnormal (market-adjusted) returns from
two days following quarter t-1’s earnings announcement date to one day
following quarter t’s earnings announcement date. Warning firms._.
Panel A: Good News Warning Firms
RMˆ∆ Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean 0.092 0.079 0.050 0.096
Std. Dev. 0.037 0.047 0.052 0.061
Max 0.169 0.156 0.161 0.217
90% 0.142 0.131 0.098 0.186
75% 0.105 0.091 0.049 0.116
Median 0.080 0.075 0.034 0.078
25% 0.070 0.067 0.029 0.061
10% 0.066 0.080 0.022 0.055
Min -0.103 -0.179 -0.001 -0.086
No. of Obs. 1,258 (100.00%) 363 (100.00%) 427 (100.00%) 468 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ 1,250 ( 99.36%) 353 ( 97.25%) 422 ( 98.83%) 458 ( 97.86%)
Negative RMˆ∆ 10 ( 0.64%) 10 ( 2.75%) 5 ( 1.17%) 10 ( 2.14%)
Panel B: Good News No-warning Firms
RMˆ∆ Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean 0.082 0.070 0.047 0.078
Std. Dev. 0.037 0.043 0.090 0.063
Max 0.148 0.128 0.182 0.185
90% 0.122 0.108 0.089 0.140
75% 0.092 0.080 0.036 0.093
Median 0.075 0.067 0.023 0.069
25% 0.068 0.062 0.018 0.059
10% 0.064 0.050 0.013 0.045
Min -0.057 -0.101 -0.020 -0.169
No. of Obs. 12,560 (100.00%) 3,620 (100.00%) 4,412 (100.00%) 4,528 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ 12,344 ( 98.28%) 3,502 ( 96.74%) 4,174 ( 98.83%) 4,352 ( 96.11%)
Negative RMˆ∆ 216 ( 1.72%) 118 ( 3.26%) 138 ( 3.13%) 176 ( 3.89%)
82
Table 8 (Continued)
Distribution of the Warning Effect after Controlling for Self-selection Bias
( RMˆ∆ )
ititit NRˆMWRˆMRMˆ∆ −= ,
where and M are estimated market reactions associated with earnings news under
warning and no-warning scenarios of firm i in quarter t.
itWRˆM itNRˆ
Panel C: Bad News Warning Firms
RMˆ∆ Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean -0.011 -0.029 -0.025 -0.006
Std. Dev. 0.043 0.050 0.076 0.036
Max 0.066 0.029 0.069 0.067
90% 0.033 0.013 0.042 0.036
75% 0.016 0.001 0.023 0.021
Median -0.005 -0.016 -0.007 -0.003
25% -0.031 -0.047 -0.050 -0.033
10% -0.060 -0.077 -0.108 -0.054
Min -0.085 -0.117 -0.154 -0.072
No. of Obs. 2,045 (100.00%) 715 (100.00%) 592 (100.00%) 738 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ 901 ( 44.06%) 189 ( 26.43%) 263 ( 44.43%) 334 ( 45.26%)
Negative RMˆ∆ 1,114 ( 55.94%) 526 ( 73.57%) 329 ( 55.57%) 404 ( 54.74%)
Panel D: Bad News No-warning Firms
RMˆ∆ Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean -0.014 -0.020 -0.020 -0.011
Std. Dev. 0.035 0.043 0.051 0.031
Max 0.035 0.022 0.020 0.050
90% 0.014 0.009 0.016 0.018
75% 0.009 0.004 0.012 0.010
Median -0.005 -0.007 -0.002 -0.005
25% -0.029 -0.031 -0.034 -0.030
10% -0.058 -0.061 -0.075 -0.055
Min -0.077 -0.084 -0.115 -0.070
No. of Obs. 7,155 (100.00%) 2,604 (100.00%) 2,355 (100.00%) 2,196 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ 3,043 (42.53%) 968 ( 37.17%) 1,083 ( 45.99%) 961 ( 43.76%)
Negative RMˆ∆ 4,112 (57.47%) 1,636 ( 62.83%) 1,272 ( 54.01%) 1,235 ( 56.24%)
83
Table 9
Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
Warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
)FGx (UEβ)FSx (UEβ)FRx (UEβUEββMRW itit
W
4itit
W
3itit
W
2it
W
1
W
0it ′+′+′+′+′=
it
W
7itit
W
6itit
W
5 AFRβ)LOSSx (UEβ)LUEx (UEβ ′+′+′+
W
ititit
W
8 e)LAFRx (AFRβ ′+′+
Panel A: Good News Warning Firms
Independent
Variables
Est.
Coeff.
Pooled Sample
1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Intercept W
0βˆ′ 0.025(0.011)
** 0.006
(0.015)
0.072
(0.018)
*** 0.008
(0.019)
UE W
1βˆ′ 11.115(3.506)
*** 12.461
(3.984)
*** 10.427
(3.989)
*** 11.874
(3.125)
***
UE x FR W
2βˆ′ 8.219(3.933)
** 9.144
(4.137)
** 9.302
(3.870)
** 5.637
(3.167)
*
UE x FS W
3βˆ′ -1.501(3.691)
-2.358
(3.373)
-1.279
(3.999)
-1.837
(3.908)
UE x FG W
4βˆ′ 1.775(3.907)
1.988
(3.077)
0.721
(3.797)
2.731
(2.730)
UE x LUE W
5βˆ′ -5.424(2.855)
* -6.105
(3.022)
** -5.622
(2.854)
** -6.409
(3.270)
**
UE x LOSS W
6βˆ′ -5.076(2.851)
* -6.957
(3.532)
** -4.900
(2.311)
** -6.143
(2.939)
**
AFR W
7βˆ′ 8.597(3.035)
*** 8.719
(2.813)
*** 10.692
(3.962)
*** 7.238
(3.531)
**
AFR x LAFR W
8βˆ′ -5.880(3.111)
* -5.325
(2.926)
* -5.021
(2.656)
* -3.018
(1.658)
*
Adj. R2 0.087 0.117 0.110 0.125
No. of Obs. 1,258 363 427 468
84
Table 9 (Continued)
Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
Warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
)FGx (UEβ)FSx (UEβ)FRx (UEβUEββMRW itit
W
4itit
W
3itit
W
2it
W
1
W
0it ′+′+′+′+′=
it
W
7itit
W
6itit
W
5 AFRβ)LOSSx (UEβ)LUEx (UEβ ′+′+′+
W
ititit
W
8 e)LAFRx (AFRβ ′+′+
Panel B: Bad News Warning Firms
Independent
Variables
Est.
Coeff.
Pooled Sample
1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Intercept W
0βˆ′ -0.134(0.012)
*** -0.120
(0.018)
*** -0.132
(0.024)
*** -0.131
(0.022)
***
UE W
1βˆ′ 6.660(2.321)
*** 5.544
(1.293)
*** 6.736
(2.723)
** 6.792
(2.302)
***
UE x FR W
2βˆ′ 3.111(1.095)
*** 2.805
(1.550)
* 3.970
(2.603)
4.992
(1.739)
***
UE x FS W
3βˆ′ -0.640(1.422)
-0.514
(1.142)
-0.463
(2.012)
-0.831
(1.278)
UE x FG W
4βˆ′ 3.685(1.423)
*** 3.158
(1.611)
** 3.355
(2.470)
5.231
(1.887)
***
UE x LUE W
5βˆ′ -2.282(1.201)
* -2.228
(1.252)
* -2.418
(1.321)
* -2.052
(1.122)
*
UE x LOSS W
6βˆ′ -2.995(1.655)
* -3.966
(1.825)
** -2.078
(1.148)
* -2.838
(1.594)
*
AFR W
7βˆ′ 11.353(2.366)
*** 13.622
(2.624)
*** 8.906
(2.356)
*** 13.144
(3.151)
***
AFR x LAFR W
8βˆ′ -6.979(2.109)
*** -7.301
(2.333)
*** -5.099
(2.601)
** -8.813
(3.005)
***
Adj. R2 0.49 0.097 0.047 0.047
No. of Obs. 2,045 715 592 738
85
Table 9 (Continued)
Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
Warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
* Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.10 level.
** Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.05 level.
*** Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.01 level.
Variable definitions:
MRWit = market reaction associated with earnings news of warning firm i in quarter t,
UEit = price-deflated unexpected earnings of warning firm i in quarter t,
FRit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if warning firm i’s return variation in
quarter t exceeds the median return variation of all sample firm-quarters (i.e., high
market risk firms) and 0 otherwise,
FSit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if warning firm i’s market capitalization
at the beginning of quarter t exceeds the median market capitalization of all sample
firm-quarters (i.e., large firms) and 0 otherwise,
FGit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if warning firm i’s book-to-market ratio at
the beginning of quarter t is at least the median book-to-market ratio of all sample
firm-quarters (i.e., high growth firms) and 0 otherwise,
LUEit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if the absolute value of price-deflated
unexpected earnings of warning firm i in quarter t is at least 0.01 (i.e., large earning
news firms) and 0 otherwise,
LOSSit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if warning firm i’s reported earnings in
quarter t is negative (i.e., loss firms) and 0 otherwise,
AFRit = price-deflated analyst forecast revisions of warning firm i in quarter t, and
LAFRit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if the absolute value of price-deflated
analyst forecast revisions of warning firm i in quarter t is at least 0.01 (i.e., large
forecast revision firms) and 0 otherwise.
86
Table 10
Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
No-warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
)FGx (UEβ)FSx (UEβ)FRx (UEβUEββMRN itit
N
4itit
N
3itit
N
2it
N
1
N
0it ′+′+′+′+′=
it
N
7itit
N
6itit
N
5 AFRβ)LOSSx (UEβ)LUEx (UEβ ′+′+′+
N
ititit
N
8 e)LAFRx (AFRβ ′+′+
Panel A: Good News No-warning Firms
Independent
Variables
Est.
Coeff.
Pooled Sample
1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Intercept N
0βˆ′ 0.018(0.003)
*** 0.026
(0.004)
*** 0.003
(0.006)
0.032
(0.006)
***
UE N
1βˆ′ 10.884(1.410)
*** 10.168
(2.759)
*** 9.591
(2.524)
*** 11.483
(2.665)
***
UE x FR N
2βˆ′ 5.476(1.530)
*** 6.831
(2.623)
*** 3.790
(2.256)
* 4.761
(2.561)
*
UE x FS N
3βˆ′ -2.877(2.387)
-2.333
(2.722)
-0.515
(2.344)
-3.048
(2.234)
UE x FG N
4βˆ′ 3.082(2.352)
0.932
(2.432)
3.173
(2.219)
2.257
(2.315)
UE x LUE N
5βˆ′ -4.825(1.327)
*** -5.512
(2.366)
** -4.576
(2.158)
** -4.567
(2.330)
**
UE x LOSS N
6βˆ′ -5.961(1.251)
*** -5.551
(2.636)
** -6.385
(2.396)
*** -5.360
(2.615)
**
AFR N
7βˆ′ 11.563(1.027)
*** 14.335
(1.624)
*** 10.045
(1.722)
*** 11.645
(1.864)
***
AFR x LAFR N
8βˆ′ -7.971(1.221)
*** -8.114
(2.154)
*** -5.261
(2.073)
** -9.429
(2.116)
***
Adj. R2 0.036 0.048 0.072 0.042
No. of Obs. 12,560 3,620 4,412 4,528
87
Table 10 (Continued)
Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
No-warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
)FGx (UEβ)FSx (UEβ)FRx (UEβUEββMRN itit
N
4itit
N
3itit
N
2it
N
1
N
0it ′+′+′+′+′=
it
N
7itit
N
6itit
N
5 AFRβ)LOSSx (UEβ)LUEx (UEβ ′+′+′+
N
ititit
N
8 e)LAFRx (AFRβ ′+′+
Panel B: Bad News No-warning Firms
Independent
Variables
Est.
Coeff.
Pooled Sample
1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Intercept N
0βˆ′ -0.034(0.005)
*** -0.028
(0.007)
*** -0.047
(0.009)
*** -0.026
(0.010)
**
UE N
1βˆ′ 4.550(1.827)
** 4.143
(2.021)
** 4.400
(1.496)
*** 5.125
(2.429)
**
UE x FR N
2βˆ′ 0.322(0.850)
0.469
(1.264)
0.773
(1.679)
0.141
(0.828)
UE x FS N
3βˆ′ -1.936(1.057)
* -0.813
(1.332)
* -2.324
(1.139)
* -0.422
(2.244)
UE x FG N
4βˆ′ 1.279(0.822)
0.892
(1.079)
0.270
(1.565)
1.537
(1.537)
UE x LUE N
5βˆ′ -2.234(1.346)
* -3.410
(1.916)
* -2.578
(1.386)
* -3.895
(2.188)
*
UE x LOSS N
6βˆ′ -2.394(0.892)
*** -3.117
(1.383)
** -2.526
(1.164)
** -2.834
(1.461)
*
AFR N
7βˆ′ 9.905(1.197)
*** 10.278
(1.639)
*** 9.692
(2.121)
*** 10.414
(2.455)
***
AFR x LAFR N
8βˆ′ -4.848(1.174)
*** -3.125
(1.594)
** -5.990
(2.100)
*** -5.497
(2.409)
**
Adj. R2 0.027 0.047 0.035 0.038
No. of Obs. 7,155 2,604 2,355 2,196
88
Table 10 (Continued)
Results of OLS Estimation of Market Reaction Model under
No-warning Scenario – without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
* Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.10 level.
** Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.05 level.
*** Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.01 level.
Variable definitions:
MRNit = market reaction associated with earnings news of no-warning firm i in quarter t,
UEit = price-deflated unexpected earnings of no-warning firm i in quarter t,
FRit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if no-warning firm i’s return variation in
quarter t exceeds the median return variation of all sample firm-quarters (i.e., high
market risk firms) and 0 otherwise,
FSit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if no-warning firm i’s market
capitalization at the beginning of quarter t exceeds the median market capitalization
of all sample firm-quarters (i.e., large firms) and 0 otherwise,
FGit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if no-warning firm i’s book-to-market
ratio at the beginning of quarter t is at least the median book-to-market ratio of all
sample firm-quarters (i.e., high growth firms) and 0 otherwise,
LUEit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if the absolute value of price-deflated
unexpected earnings of no-warning firm i in quarter t is at least 0.01 (i.e., large
earning news firms) and 0 otherwise,
LOSSit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if no-warning firm i’s reported earnings
in quarter t is negative (i.e., loss firms) and 0 otherwise,
AFRit = price-deflated analyst forecast revisions of no-warning firm i in quarter t, and
LAFRit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if the absolute value of price-deflated
analyst forecast revisions of no-warning firm i in quarter t is at least 0.01 (i.e., large
forecast revision firms) and 0 otherwise.
89
Table 11
Distribution of the Warning Effect without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
( RMˆ∆ ′ )
ititit NRˆMWRˆMRMˆ∆ ′−′=′ ,
where and M are estimated market reactions associated with earnings news under
warning and no-warning scenarios without IMR, of firm i in quarter t.
itWRˆM ′ itNRˆ ′
Panel A: Good News Warning Firms
RMˆ∆ ′ Pooled Sample 1998-2000 Subsample 1998 Subsample 1999 Subsample 2000
Mean 0.085 0.065 0.036 0.093
Std. Dev. 0.040 0.050 0.054 0.060
Max 0.168 0.147 0.141 0.212
90% 0.141 0.120 0.091 0.180
75% 0.099 0.078 0.035 0.113
Median 0.071 0.058 0.018 0.076
25% 0.061 0.049 0.012 0.061
10% 0.057 0.044 0.006 0.055
Min -0.110 -0.186 -0.012 -0.101
No. of Obs. 1,258 (100.00%) 363 (100.00%) 427 (100.00%) 468 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ ′ 1,248 ( 99.21%) 347 ( 95.59%) 412 ( 96.49%) 455 ( 97.22%)
Negative RMˆ∆ ′ 10 ( 0.79%) 16 ( 4.41%) 15 ( 3.51%) 13 ( 2.78%)
Panel B: Good News No-warning Firms
RMˆ∆ ′ Pooled Sample 1998-2000 Subsample 1998 Subsample 1999 Subsample 2000
Mean 0.074 0.057 0.040 0.074
Std. Dev. 0.042 0.048 0.087 0.064
Max 0.146 0.117 0.172 0.177
90% 0.117 0.098 0.086 0.135
75% 0.084 0.069 0.032 0.090
Median 0.066 0.054 0.016 0.067
25% 0.059 0.048 0.011 0.057
10% 0.055 0.039 0.007 0.038
Min -0.094 -0.129 -0.025 -0.190
No. of Obs. 12,560 (100.00%) 3620 (100.00%) 4,412 (100.00%) 4,528 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ ′ 12,305 ( 97.97%) 3468 ( 95.80%) 4,228 ( 95.83%) 4,328 ( 95.58%)
Negative RMˆ∆ ′ 255 ( 2.03%) 152 ( 4.20%) 184 ( 4.17%) 200 ( 4.42%)
90
Table 11 (Continued)
Distribution of the Warning Effect without Controlling for Self-selection Bias
( RMˆ∆ ′ )
ititit NRˆMWRˆMRMˆ∆ ′−′=′ ,
where and M are estimated market reactions associated with earnings news under
warning and no-warning scenarios without IMR, of firm i in quarter t.
itWRˆM ′ itNRˆ ′
Panel C: Bad News Warning Firms
RMˆ∆ ′ Pooled Sample 1998-2000 Subsample 1998 Subsample 1999 Subsample 2000
Mean -0.030 -0.037 -0.043 -0.036
Std. Dev. 0.034 0.047 0.058 0.032
Max 0.055 0.022 0.031 0.079
90% -0.007 -0.001 0.001 0.001
75% -0.014 -0.010 -0.009 -0.027
Median -0.024 -0.024 -0.028 -0.042
25% -0.042 -0.050 -0.059 -0.055
10% -0.064 -0.080 -0.102 -0.067
Min -0.084 -0.124 -0.143 -0.073
No. of Obs. 2,045 (100.00%) 715 (100.00%) 592 (100.00%) 738 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ ′ 151 ( 7.38%) 70 ( 9.79%) 67 ( 11.32%) 81 ( 10.98%)
Negative RMˆ∆ ′ 1,894 ( 92.62%) 645 ( 90.21%) 525 ( 88.68%) 657 ( 89.02%)
Panel D: Bad News No-warning Firms
RMˆ∆ ′ Pooled Sample 1998-2000 Subsample 1998 Subsample 1999 Subsample 2000
Mean -0.032 -0.027 -0.029 -0.029
Std. Dev. 0.025 0.040 0.037 0.019
Max 0.030 0.016 0.005 0.040
90% -0.019 -0.003 -0.006 -0.012
75% -0.021 -0.007 -0.008 -0.025
Median -0.026 -0.016 -0.017 -0.030
25% -0.039 -0.034 -0.036 -0.038
10% -0.057 -0.063 -0.067 -0.048
Min -0.074 -0.084 -0.095 -0.054
No. of Obs. 7,155 (100.00%) 2,604 (100.00%) 2,355 (100.00%) 2,196 (100.00%)
Positive RMˆ∆ ′ 184 ( 2.57%) 162 ( 6.22%) 18 ( 0.76%) 132 ( 6.01%)
Negative RMˆ∆ ′ 6,971 (97.43%) 2,442 ( 93.78%) 2,337 ( 99.24%) 2,064 ( 93.99%)
91
Table 12
Distribution of Self-selection Bias ( ) in the Warning Effect BSˆS
ititit RMˆRMˆBSˆS ∆−′∆= ,
where is the warning effect without controlling for self-selection bias and is the
warning effect after controlling for self-selection bias of firm i in quarter t.
itRMˆ ′∆ itRMˆ∆
Panel A: Good News Warning Firms
BSˆS Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean -0.007 -0.014 -0.013 -0.003
Std. Dev. 0.004 0.008 0.006 0.004
Max 0.005 0.010 0.014 0.002
90% -0.002 -0.003 -0.007 -0.000
75% -0.005 -0.011 -0.012 -0.001
Median -0.007 -0.016 -0.015 -0.002
25% -0.008 -0.019 -0.016 -0.004
10% -0.009 -0.020 -0.017 -0.008
Min -0.022 -0.028 -0.031 -0.020
No. of Obs. 1,258 (100.00%) 363 (100.00%) 427 (100.00%) 468 (100.00%)
Positive BSˆS 26 ( 7.16%) 15 ( 3.51%) 20 ( 4.27%)
Negative S BSˆ 1,194 ( 94.91%) 337 ( 92.84%) 412 ( 96.49%) 448 ( 95.73%)
64 ( 5.09%)
Panel B: Good News No-warning Firms
BSˆS Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean -0.008 -0.012 -0.006 -0.003
Std. Dev. 0.005 0.008 0.007 0.004
Max 0.002 0.008 0.015 0.001
90% -0.004 -0.004 -0.001 -0.001
75% -0.006 -0.010 -0.004 -0.001
Median -0.008 -0.013 -0.007 -0.002
25% -0.009 -0.014 -0.008 -0.004
10% -0.010 -0.016 -0.009 -0.008
Min -0.035 -0.035 -0.033 -0.023
No. of Obs. 12,560 (100.00%) 3,620 (100.00%) 4,412 (100.00%) 4,528 (100.00%)
Positive S BSˆ 298 ( 2.37%) 192 ( 5.30%) 332 ( 7.52%) 106 ( 2.34%)
Negative S BSˆ 12,262 ( 97.63%) 3,428 ( 94.70%) 4,080 ( 92.48%) 4,422 ( 97.66%)
92
Table 12 (Continued)
Distribution of Self-selection Bias ( ) in the Warning Effect BSˆS
ititit RMˆRMˆBSˆS ∆−′∆= ,
where is the warning effect without controlling for self-selection bias and is the
warning effect after controlling for self-selection bias of firm i in quarter t.
itRMˆ ′∆ itRMˆ∆
Panel C: Bad News Warning Firms
BSˆS Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean -0.018 -0.007 -0.018 -0.029
Std. Dev. 0.019 0.006 0.021 0.031
Max 0.041 0.007 0.073 0.073
90% 0.012 0.001 0.008 0.009
75% -0.006 -0.003 -0.007 -0.010
Median -0.019 -0.008 -0.021 -0.031
25% -0.032 -0.012 -0.033 -0.052
10% -0.042 -0.015 -0.041 -0.069
Min -0.048 -0.018 0.047 -0.076
No. of Obs. 2,045 (100.00%) 715 (100.00%) 592 (100.00%) 738 (100.00%)
Positive S BSˆ 316 ( 15.45%) 100 ( 13.99%) 99 ( 16.72%) 112 ( 15.18%)
Negative S BSˆ 1,729 ( 84.55%) 615 ( 86.01%) 493 ( 83.28%) 626 ( 84.82%)
Panel D: Bad News No-warning Firms
BSˆS Pooled Sample 1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Mean -0.018 -0.007 -0.009 -0.018
Std. Dev. 0.016 0.006 0.016 0.024
Max 0.030 0.008 0.043 0.053
90% 0.005 0.001 0.012 0.015
75% -0.008 -0.003 -0.001 -0.003
Median -0.022 -0.009 -0.014 -0.022
25% -0.031 -0.012 -0.021 -0.036
10% -0.034 -0.014 -0.024 -0.042
Min -0.041 -0.016 -0.028 -0.058
No. of Obs. 7,155 (100.00%) 2,604 (100.00%) 2,355 (100.00%) 2,196 (100.00%)
Positive S BSˆ 1,039 ( 14.52%) 366 ( 14.06%) 525 ( 22.29%) 459 ( 20.90%)
Negative S BSˆ 6,116 ( 85.48%) 2,238 ( 85.94%) 1,830 ( 77.71%) 1,737 ( 79.10%)
93
Table 13
Results of Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Warning Choice Model
it5it4it3it2it10it PWPδLMVδUEδHLRδRMˆ∆δδWARN +++++=
itit8it7it6 εFXFδREGδNAFδ ++++
Panel A: Good News Firms
Independent
Variables
Est.
Coeff.
Pooled Sample
1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Constant
0δˆ
-2.401
(0.085)
*** -2.700
(0.179)
*** -2.233
(0.137)
*** -2.505
(0.142)
***
RMˆ∆ 1δˆ
2.764
(0.476)
*** 3.390
(0.695)
*** 1.703
(0.373)
*** 2.927
(0.542)
***
HLR
2δˆ
0.033
(0.034)
0.028
(0.063)
0.002
(0.058)
0.038
(0.058)
UE
3δˆ 13.070(5.131)
** 13.447
(5.384)
** 12.025
(6.135)
** 13.167
(6.670)
**
LMV
4δˆ 0.087(0.012)
*** 0.121
(0.023)
*** 0.065
(0.020)
** 0.088
(0.019)
***
PWP
5δˆ 0.624(0.032)
*** 0.582
(0.060)
*** 0.672
(0.055)
*** 0.646
(0.053)
***
NAF
6δˆ 0.001(0.004)
0.012
(0.010)
0.017
(0.008)
** 0.007
(0.007)
REG
7δˆ -0.318(0.057)
*** -0.381
(0.117)
** -0.315
(0.101)
** -0.307
(0.090)
***
FXF
8δˆ 0.071(0.043)
0.026
(0.085)
0.018
(0.077)
0.195
(0.069)
***
No. of Obs. 13,818 3,983 4,839 4,996
% Correct 93.62% 93.30% 93.80% 92.25%
94
Table 13 (Continued)
Results of Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Warning Choice Model
it5it4it3it2it10it PWPδLMVδUEδHLRδRMˆ∆δδWARN +++++=
itit8it7it6 εFXFδREGδNAFδ ++++
Panel B: Bad News Firms
Independent
Variables
Est.
Coeff.
Pooled Sample
1998-2000
Subsample
1998
Subsample
1999
Subsample
2000
Constant
0δˆ
-1.794
(0.077)
*** -1.515
(0.127)
*** -1.924
(0.140)
*** -1.855
(0.143)
***
∆MR
1δˆ
1.585
(0.443)
*** 1.847
(0.695)
*** 1.194
(0.553)
** 1.722
(0.803)
**
HLR
2δˆ
0.166
(0.034)
*** 0.156
(0.057)
*** 0.126
(0.061)
** 0.152
(0.058)
***
UE
3δˆ -13.180(3.952)
*** -13.234
(3.766)
*** -13.916
(4.125)
*** -11.738
(3.826)
***
LMV
4δˆ 0.087(0.012)
*** 0.060
(0.020)
*** 0.096
(0.021)
*** 0.099
(0.021)
***
PWP
5δˆ 0.546(0.031)
*** 0.549
(0.054)
*** 0.567
(0.056)
*** 0.545
(0.054)
***
NAF
6δˆ 0.006(0.005)
0.001
(0.008)
0.003
(0.008)
0.014
(0.008)
*
REG
7δˆ -0.433(0.054)
*** -0.463
(0.097)
*** -0.375
(0.095)
*** -0.470
(0.092)
***
FXF
8δˆ 0.056(0.048)
0.009
(0.084)
0.070
(0.092)
0.089
(0.079)
No. of Obs. 9,200 3,319 2,947 2,934
% Correct: 83.63% 83.94% 83.71% 81.60%
95
Table 13 (Continued)
Results of Probit Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Warning Choice Model
* Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.10 level.
** Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.05 level.
*** Statistically significant at two-tailed 0.01 level.
Variable definitions:
WARNit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if firm i issues earnings warnings for
quarter t and 0 otherwise,
∆MRit = the warning effect, calculated as the estimated market reaction associated with
earnings news under a warning scenario minus that under a no-warning scenario of
firm i in quarter t.
HLRit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if firm i is a member of high litigation
risk industries (i.e., high litigation risk firms) and 0 otherwise,
UEit = price-deflated unexpected earnings of firm i in quarter t,
LMVit = log of firm i’s market capitalization at the beginning of quarter t,
PWPit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if firm i issues earnings warnings in any
of its past four quarters (i.e., quarters t-4 to t-1) and 0 otherwise,
NAFit = number of individual analysts who follow firm i in quarter t,
REGit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if firm i is a member of regulated
industries (i.e., regulated firms) and 0 otherwise, and
FXFit = a dichotomous variable taking a value of 1 if firm i issues either debt or equity within
the next four quarters (i.e., quarters t+1 to t+4) and 0 otherwise.
96
References
Ajinkya, B. and M. Gift. 1984. Corporate Managers’ Earnings Forecasts and
Symmetrical Adjustments of Market Expectations. Journal of Accounting
Research 22, 425-444.
Atiase, R. K. 1985. Predisclosure Information, Firm Capitalization and Security
Price Behavior Around Earnings Announcements. Journal of Accounting
Research, Spring: 21-35.
Atiase, R. K., S. Supattarakul, and S. Tse. 2003. Market Reaction to Earnings
Surprise Warnings: The Incremental Role of Shareholder Litigation Risk
on the Warning Effect. Working Paper at The University of Texas at
Austin.
Baginski, S. P., J. M. Hassell, and M. D. Kimbrough. 2002. The Effect of Legal
Environment on Voluntary Disclosure: Evidence from Management
Earnings Forecasts Issued in U.S. and Canadian Markets. The Accounting
Review, January: 25-50.
Baginski, S. P., J. M. Hassell, and G. Waymire. 1994 Some Evidence on the
News Content of Preliminary Earnings Estimates. The Accounting Review,
January: 265-271.
Bamber, L. S. 1987. Unexpected Earnings, Firm Size, and Trading Volume
around Quarterly Earnings Announcements. The Accounting Review, July:
510-532.
Botosan, C. A. 1997. Disclosure Level and the Cost of Equity Capital. The
Accounting Review, July: 323-350.
Chambers, D. J., R. N. Freeman, and A. S. Koch. 1999. The Role of Risk in Price-
Earnings Relations. Working Paper at The University of Illinois at
Urbana-Champaign and The University of Texas at Austin.
Chen, S. 2002. Managerial Guidance of Market’s Expectations: Incentives and
Effects. Working Paper at University of Southern California.
97
Collins, D., and S. Kothari. 1989 An Analysis of Intertemporal and Cross-
Sectional Determinants of Earnings Response Coefficients. Journal of
Accounting and Economics, July: 143-181.
Core, J. E. 2001. A Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature: Discussion.
Journal of Accounting and Economics 31: 441-456.
Cornell B., and W. R. Landsman. 1989. Security Price Response to Quarterly
Earnings Announcements and Analysts’ Forecast Revision. The
Accounting Review, October: 692-701.
Cox, C. T. 1985. Further Evidence on the Representativeness of Management
Earnings Forecasts. The Accounting Review, October: 692-701.
Easton, P., and M. Zmijewski. 1989. Cross-Sectional Variation in the Stock
Market Response to Accounting Earnings Announcements. Journal of
Accounting and Economics, July: 117-141.
Francis, J., D. Philbrick, and K. Schipper. 1994. Shareholder Litigation and
Corporate Disclosures. Journal of Accounting Research, Autumn:
137-164.
Frankel, R., M. Mcnichols, and P. Wilson. 1995. Discretionary Disclosure and
External Financing. The Accounting Review, January: 135-150.
Freeman, R. 1987. The Association between Accounting Earnings and Security
Returns for Large and Small Firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics
9: 195-228.
Freeman, R., and S. Tse. 1992. A Nonlinear Model of Security Price Responses to
Unexpected Earnings. Journal of Accounting Research, Autumn: 185-209.
Hayn, C. 1995. The Information Content of Losses. Journal of Accounting and
Economics 2: 125-153.
Healy, P., and K. Palepu. 2001. Information Asymmetry, Corporate Disclosure,
and the Capital Markets: A Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature.
Journal of Accounting and Economic 31: 405-440.
Hovanesian, M. D. 2000. Earnings: Excuses, Excuses, Excuses. Business Week,
July 24.
98
Ip, G. 1997. Rise in Profit Guidance Dilutes Positive Surprises. The Wall Street
Journal, June 23.
Kasznik, R., and B. Lev. 1995. To Warn or Not to Warn: Management Disclosure
in the Face of an Earnings Surprise. The Accounting Review, January:
113-134.
King, R., G. Pownell, and G. Waymire. 1990. Expectations Adjustment via
Timely Management Forecasts: Review, Synthesis, and Suggestions for
Future Research. Journal of Accounting Literature 9: 113-144.
Kormendi, R. and R. Lipe. 1987. Earnings Innovations, Earnings Persistence, and
Stock Returns. Journal of Business, July: 513-526.
Kross W., W. G. Lewellen, and B. T. Ro. 1994. Evidence on the Motivation for
Management Forecasts of Corporate Earnings. Managerial and Decision
Economics 15: 187-200.
Lang M., and R. Lundholm. 1993. Cross-Sectional Determinants of Analyst
Ratings of Corporate Disclosures. Journal of Accounting Research,
Autumn: 246-271.
Lee, L. F. 1978. Unionism and Wage Rates: A Simultaneous Equations Model
with Qualitative and Limited Dependent Variables. International
Economic Review, June: 415-433.
Libby, R., and H. Tan. 1999. Analysts’ Reactions to Warnings of Negative
Earnings Surprises. Journal of Accounting Research, Autumn: 415-435.
Maddala, G. S. 1983. Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in
Econometrics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Maddala, G. S. 1991. A Perspective on the Use of Limited Dependent and
Qualitative Variables Models in Accounting Research. The Accounting
Review, October: 788-807.
McLean, B. 2001. “Confession Season” is Getting Pretty Ugly. Fortune,
January 8.
Miller, G. S., and J. D. Piotroski. 2000. Forward-Looking Earnings Statements:
Determinants and Market Response. Working Paper at Harvard University
and The University of Chicago.
99
Ruland W., S. Tung, and N. E. George. 1990. Factors Associated with the
Disclosure of Managers’ Forecasts. The Accounting Review, July:
710-721.
Sengupta, P. 1998. Corporate Disclosure Quality and the Cost of Debt. The
Accounting Review, October: 459-474.
Shu, S. 2001. Why Do Firms Issue Earnings Warnings: A Self-Selection
Analysis. Working Paper at Boston College.
Skinner, D. 1994. Why Firms Voluntarily Disclose Bad News. Journal of
Accounting Research, Spring: 38-60.
Skinner, D. 1997. Earnings Disclosures and Stockholder Lawsuits. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 23: 249-282.
Soffer, L. C., S. R. Thiagarajan, and B. R. Walther. 2000. Earnings
Preannouncement Strategies. Review of Accounting Studies, March: 5-26.
Stone, A. 2002. Earnings: Another Season of Discontent? Business Week,
September 12.
Wahlegren, E. 2002. A Sober Look at Third-Quarter Earnings. Business Week,
October 28.
Vickers, M. 1999. Ho-hum, Another Earnings Surprise. Business Week, May 24.
Waymire, G. 1985. Earnings Volatility and Voluntary Management Forecast
Disclosure. Journal of Accounting Research, Spring: 268-95.
100
101
Vita
Somchai Supattarakul was born in Saraburi, Thailand on November 18,
1967, the son of Orapin and Prasert Supattarakul. He earned the degrees of
Bachelor of Business Administration in Accounting in October 1988 and Master
of Business Administration in May 1994 from Thammasat University, Thailand.
He joined SGVN Arthur Andersen – Thailand as an auditor in October 1988 and
Thammasat University as an accounting lecturer in January 1993. In May 1996,
he received the degree of Master of Professional Accounting from The University
of Texas at Austin with the financial support of Faculty of Commerce and
Accountancy, Thammasat University where he returned to work for after
graduation. In September 1998 he entered the Ph.D. Program in Accounting at
The University of Texas at Austin.
Permanent address: 11 Saeree-Thai Rd., Klongjun, Bangkapi, Bangkok 10240
Thailand
This dissertation was typed by the author.
._.
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- CH1082.PDF